The
Social
Housing
Question
As New Yorkers look to the past, present, and future
of social housing, we find more questions than answers.
SAMUEL STEIN
Over the past nineteen years, I have lived in
twelve New York City apartments. Nine of
them were rent stabilized; in four of those
my name was on the lease, and in five of them
I was a subletter or a roommate. There were
two market-rate apartments, one of which
was really an illegal single room occupancy.
I was evicted from one of the subletted
rent stabilized apartments. You’re supposed
to get the landlord’s permission when you
sublet a rent stabilized apartment, but in
this case the leaseholder didn’t want to do
that because the landlord was in prison for
attempting to kill the downstairs neighbor
and burn down the building. Before the landlord went to prison, though, he seems to have
passed the building—and several others he
owned—to his brother, whose limited liability company collected the rent (and at least
in my building didn’t do much else). Shortly
before the old landlord was set to be released
from prison, the brother hired a private
detective to sniff out any renters whose
tenancies weren’t 100 percent kosher. The
leaseholder got me a lawyer, but all he could
secure was time and money to move. On the
matter of the lease, the law was on the side of
the landlord, who had tried to kill his tenant
and destroy his building.
This is antisocial housing. It’s an
extreme case, but it demonstrates just how
psychotic the landlord-tenant power relation can be, even under rent regulation.
Landlords not only extract thousands from
tenants each month, but they hold a monopoly over tenants’ ability to exist in a place,
and they will revoke it if their terms aren’t
met—or, in the absence of rent regulation,
whenever they feel like it.
Now I live in what I see as a form of
social housing: a limited-equity cooperative
run under the Housing Development Fund
Corporation (HDFC) model. In 1979, after
years of milking his buildings for rent and
not paying his taxes, the owner of eight adjacent tenements in Hell’s Kitchen abandoned
the properties. The city took them over and,
through an experimental program of the US
Department of Housing and Urban Development, it hired tenants and other nonresident
workers to fix up the apartments and, two
years later, sold them back to the tenants for
cheap under two conditions: when they sold
their shares they couldn’t make much profit,
and the buyers had to be in a similar income
bracket. When I moved in thirty-nine years
later, the cost of the apartment was more
than I wanted to pay but about half the going
rate for the area. I pay a reasonable mortgage and a very low maintenance fee, since
there’s no landlord and no speculative debt
on the buildings. I share governance with
fifty other households. Because we can’t
make much profit off the sale of our apartments, we’re not concerned about things
that will raise or lower our property values.
There are plenty of disagreements among
neighbors, but the ethos of the place is all
about the collective use value of our home.
Many New Yorkers want exactly what I
have found, and since moving in I’ve worked
with many others in the housing movement
on proposals to produce dramatically more
of it. Indeed, in cities throughout North
America, the demand for social housing is
growing more intense. The term, which is in
common usage just about everywhere else
in the world, was last taken up in the US in
the 1920s and ’30s by the housing left. But
the idea has come to be embraced again by
people who seek an alternative to our hypercommodified and financialized housing
market and to bring attention to the failures
of much existing affordable housing policy,
which, contrary to its stated agenda, seems
to produce too little and too expensive housing.
For better and for worse, “social hous-
6
Illustration by PETE GAMLEN
ing” can be a slippery term, with different
people using it to mean different things. One
of the first documents to spark this resurgence of US left interest, Saoirse Gowan and
Ryan Cooper’s 2018 People’s Policy Project report Social Housing in the United
States, does not define it at all but imagines a network of mixed-income municipally
owned rental buildings. A 2020 report
produced by the Community Service Society
of New York (where I now work) called How
Social Is That Housing? characterized social
housing as having three core features—
decommodification, social equality, and
resident control—that can be found to varying degrees in housing models ranging from
public rentals to limited-equity cooperatives on community land trusts. Sociologists
Gianpaolo Baiocchi and Jake Carlson added
decarbonization as a fourth feature to aspire
to, given that many calls for social housing
now specifically preface the term with the
word green.
These definitional debates are important, but the lack of consensus around the
term has not slowed its growing popularity as a political demand. There are many
factors that account for this rise in social
housing energy on the American left: a real
desire for the housing movement to shift
from organizing against what we don’t like
(high rents and shitty landlords and developers) to what we truly want (homes for all); a
rising awareness that some other cities have
much better housing for a lot less money
than we do, with Vienna and Singapore being
common frames of reference; and democratic socialist and socialist-aligned elected
officials spreading the word about social
housing to a larger audience. In New York,
organizers are building a movement for
social housing, knocking on doors, producing policy proposals, publishing reports
that explain the idea, and sponsoring a
visit to Vienna by a delegation of tenants,
NYRA #38
homeless people, politicians, and researchers like me. Around the country, there are
several social housing campaigns at different stages: Montgomery County, Maryland,
has a public developer that’s building new
housing; Rhode Island and Atlanta are about
to do something similar; residents of Seattle voted to create a new public developer;
and there are multiple legislative proposals
to do so in California, Hawaii, and elsewhere. While it would be an exaggeration to
say that social housing is on the American
political agenda, there is more energy being
put toward the idea than there has been for
several decades.
WHATEVER YOUR DEFINITION of social
housing, most would agree that New York
has more of it than any other city in the
United States. Part of the reason is just
the size of the city—New York has more of
most things than most places in this country, even if we also don’t have nearly enough
of many things we need. But there has also
been a historic commitment to social housing (if not always under that name) among
working-class organizations and elements of
the state, as well as fractions of capital that
invest in such limited-profit projects.
Probably the longest standing form of
social housing in New York is union-built
limited-equity cooperatives. From the 1920s
to the 1970s, unions and leftist political
organizations built roughly 50,000 apartments that would be bought and sold without
profit, managed by residents, and priced for
the working class. (Many—but not all—of
these co-ops were built using the Mitchell-Lama program, which we’ll come to
shortly.) At first, union co-ops were concentrated in The Bronx, south of Van Cortlandt
Park, and were developed mostly by Jewish
leftists with varying political tendencies—
the United Workers Cooperatives for the
Communists, the Sholem Aleichem Houses
for the Bundists, the Farband Houses for the
Labor Zionists, the Amalgamated Houses
for the social democratic garment workers
unionists. The developments were built in a
neo-Tudor style with generous outdoor and
indoor public spaces dedicated to all aspects
of social life. Over time, unions became the
primary developers, spreading to Manhattan, Brooklyn, and Queens and throwing
up large-scale complexes that ranged from
ornate designs of midrise courtyard buildings to more minimalist towers in the park,
culminating finally in the northeast Bronx’s
massive Co-op City, with over 15,000 homes.
Most were built by the garment workers
union through its nonprofit United Housing Foundation, but other unions got in on
the project, too. The electricians developed
Electchester in Pomonok; the meatcutters
made Patrick E. Gorman Housing in Crown
Heights; the typographers built Big Six
Towers in Woodside; the furriers sponsored
Sam Burt Houses in Coney Island. The last
union-sponsored project—which the union
itself didn’t complete—was 1199 Houses
in East Harlem, an architecturally ambitious project sponsored by the city’s biggest
health care workers union.
These projects were financed with union
pension dollars, but they also benefited
from state support in the form of favorable
tax status and mortgages and sometimes
discounted land. Union-friendly banks
provided additional financing for the projects. Many of the projects, especially after
the early years filling in formerly pastoral parts of The Bronx, were built on federal
urban renewal sites. A lot of the time,
that meant the government evicted large
numbers of poorer people to make room for
new developments that, while geared toward
the working class, were not as cheap as the
subpar housing they replaced. Few who
were displaced were rehoused in the resulting projects. In other words, rather than
building new housing for those suffering the
worst conditions, these developments often
built very nice housing for low-wage workers
on land where even lower-wage workers lived
before. Take the case of Penn South, the
United Housing Foundation’s megaproject in
Chelsea: nearly 7,000 people were displaced
to house a different 7,000 people, pitting
worker against worker and tenant against
tenant. It is a historical irony, however, that
housing created through displacement of the
poor is some of the last remaining affordable
housing in that hypergentrified neighborhood.
Not all the labor co-ops remained affordable. Some failed fairly quickly, becoming
regulated rentals instead. Much later on,
after their initial mortgages were paid off,
some “cooperators” voted to exit the Mitchell-Lama program and become market-rate
homeowners. That meant their taxes went
up, but they were then able to sell for a windfall profit. It also meant the stock of social
housing shrank by several thousand units,
particularly in neighborhoods where potential sales prices were highest. A slew of labor
co-ops in the Lower East Side, for example,
went private as the neighborhood gentrified.
But most are still affordable and commonly
owned, with the same kinds of workers they
were built to house occupying the apartments.
As unions were building cooperatives,
the City of New York also built some of
the country’s first government-owned and
-operated housing. This model would go on to
inspire the federal public housing program,
which would become the country’s largest—and eventually most maligned and
underfunded—social housing program.
In 1935, New York City opened its first
public housing development, First Houses,
named both to mark the occasion and to
Just under
9 percent of
New York City’s
housing stock
is social housing,
and 91 percent
is not. Compared
with other US
cities, that’s a lot;
compared with
cities known for
their social housing,
like Singapore
or Vienna,
it is not.
REPORTAGE: THE SOCIAL HOUSING QUESTION
express the ambition that more was on
the way. Mayor Fiorello La Guardia and
the newly formed New York City Housing
Authority (NYCHA) originally planned to
buy a block of crumbling tenements owned
by an exploitive slumlord and renovate
them into modern housing in the heart of
the Lower East Side. Setting the scene for
dynamics to come, however, NYCHA found
it was too difficult and costly to renovate
existing buildings and so instead knocked
them down and built new structures. While
later public housing would be characterized by relatively low-density towers in the
park, First Houses more or less re-created
the streetscape that was there before, with
four- and five-story buildings lined up in a
neat row. Shortly thereafter, the New Deal’s
Works Progress Administration set out to
construct larger public housing complexes
in Williamsburg and Harlem, putting a good
deal of care into their design and setting
them up as public campuses with plenty of
usable outdoor space.
Following the Housing Act of 1937,
NYCHA began building a massive amount
of public housing, which, while not touching every corner of the city equally (there
is very little of such housing in Staten
Island, south Brooklyn, or eastern Queens,
for example), went on to cover about 80
percent of the city’s fifty-nine community
districts. As of 2023, the city’s public housing stock comprises 274 developments,
with 2,103 buildings holding 161,585 apartments. Officially, 324,253 people live in this
housing; however, everybody knows that
the real number is far higher, given that
many households take in additional people
off lease. Even based on the official count,
though, more people live in public housing
in New York than the respective populations of Newark, Pittsburgh, Cincinnati, or
St. Louis. In part in exchange for scale and
in part to prevent competition with powerful
real estate actors, the federal government
limited all public housing authorities’ design
and material budgets and restricted the
housing to very low-income city dwellers.
Though often derided for its simple
tower in the park designs, the architecture of New York City public housing is not
all that dissimilar from that of more valorized housing models, like much of the
Mitchell-Lama housing stock or rent stabilized complexes like Stuyvesant Town.
(One conspicuous commonality? Nearly all
share similarly patterned brickwork, and
lots of it.) The difference, however, is that
developments like Stuyvesant Town were
relatively well funded, whereas public housing has been continuously disinvested. The
federal government stopped building public
housing at a large scale in the 1970s, shifting first to private subsidies and next to
tax credits. Over the course of the ’80s and
’90s, the federal public housing budget was
slashed repeatedly. Ever since, the federal
government has refused to pay what it costs
to operate public housing, while simultaneously imposing rules on public housing
authorities, making their operations more
costly and difficult. While public housing developments slowly deteriorated over
this time, the yawning budget gaps and
unhealthy living conditions accelerated
in the early 2000s during the Bloomberg
mayoralty. In 2011, when Obama’s Department of Housing and Urban Development
(HUD) offered public housing authorities a
program to raise money by privatizing building ownership, NYCHA did not immediately
join in. Before long, however, the de Blasio
administration committed to privatizing
one-third of the public housing stock. More
recently, the state of New York created a
public preservation trust as an alternative
pathway—essentially turning manage7
THE SOCIAL HOUSING
WE HAVE
⬤LABOR CO-OPS
From the late 1920s to the early
1970s, unions and labor-affiliated organizations built roughly
50,000 homes in twenty-five
developments across the city.
Intended primarily for union workers, these apartments were sold
at below-market costs and were
not intended to be profitable for
residents upon resale.
⬤PUBLIC HOUSING
From the 1930s through the
1970s, New York City and the
federal government built over
175,000 public housing apartments in 335 developments around
the city. These public rentals are
available to low-income New
Yorkers and charge 30 percent of
income as rent.
⬤MITCHELL-LAMA
From the 1950s to the 1980s,
developers (often backed by union
pension funds, insurance pools, or
other sources of collective capital) built 269 “Mitchell-Lama”
developments (named after the
sponsors of the enabling legislation) containing 69,000 co-op
apartments and 66,000 rentals.
The co-ops operated under similar
rules to labor co-ops, while the
rentals charged rents based on
buildings’ operating costs, plus a
capped profit margin.
⬤HOUSING DEVELOPMENT
FUND CORPORATIONS
(HDFCs)
During the 1980s and 1990s
(and sometimes before and
sometimes afterward), the city
took possession of roughly 1,100
tax-delinquent for-profit rental
buildings with 25,000 apartments and converted them into
tenant-controlled limited-equity
co-ops known as HDFCs. While
some have notoriously skirted the
rules and spirit of the program,
most remain affordable homes for
low-income households.
⬤COMMUNITY LAND
TRUSTS (CLTs) AND MUTUAL
HOUSING ASSOCIATIONS
(MHAs)
Community groups around the city
are calling for land to be put into
CLTs (nonprofit ownership with
resident, community, and expert
guidance) and for buildings to be
put into MHAs (nonprofit rental
housing where tenants control the
board of the ownership entity) in
order to expand affordability and
resident democracy. Two neighborhoods (the Cooper Square
section of the Lower East Side and
a stretch of East Harlem) are now
known for success with this practice, but CLTs have formed around
the city in search of opportunities
to take over land and buildings.
8
ment over to a new public
entity that is eligible for the
same federal funding and debt
sources that a private developer might receive—but this
model is so far untested. Polling
among public housing residents is scant, but what we have
suggests a high degree of frustration with declining services
and crumbling architecture; a
great amount of distrust of the
institutions that maintain it;
and an even split over desires for
the future, with some residents
fighting to preserve its public
character while others push for
private management.
As NYCHA was building
public housing and as unions
were building limited equity
co-ops, the New York State
Legislature created a new
program that would combine
elements of the two. Named
after the bill’s principal sponsors, Mitchell-Lama housing
would be of two varieties: limited-equity cooperatives and
subsidized rentals, both built by
limited-profit housing companies. Some were built by unions,
while others were built by spinoffs of insurance companies and
other private actors with money
to invest in mass housing. From
1955 to 1981, New York City
saw the construction of 69,000
Mitchell-Lama co-op apartments and 66,000 rentals.
Under this program, developers received low-interest loans
and property tax abatements
and could earn up to 6 percent
annual profits. In the co-ops, the
apartment prices were and are
priced far below market rates
(though still higher than some
workers can afford), but the
shareholders cannot make any
profit on them upon resale and
in the meantime pay a monthly
maintenance fee pegged to their
buildings’ operating costs. In the
rentals, monthly rents are based
on building operating costs,
plus no more than the profit cap
allows. Though the program was
envisioned for middle-income
workers, many Mitchell-Lama
rentals were subsumed into the
federal Project-Based Section 8
program, allowing more low-income people to afford the rents.
The profit cap, however, was
raised from 6 percent to 7.5
percent in 1969 as an added
benefit to owners.
Mitchell-Lama housing—particularly the
co-ops—remains incredibly
popular among New Yorkers,
who often endure years on waiting lists to access the housing.
The prices are far lower than
market rate, the quality (again,
especially in the co-ops) tends
to be fairly high, and those
long waiting lists suggest that
plenty of people would trade
the possibility of windfall profits for the opportunity to live
decently without paying exorbitant prices. The buildings are
often high-rises, sometimes
in clusters and sometimes as
stand-alone towers. Some are
simple slabs with balconies;
others are more experimental,
such as the Brutalist Tracey
Towers in Jerome Park, with
its gigantic concrete tubes and
setback balconies or Waterside
Plaza in Kips Bay, east of FDR
Drive, whose geometrical brick
high-rises look as if they were
twisted like Rubik’s Cubes. The
interiors tend to be more generous than those in public housing,
with greater attention paid to
ventilation, light, and entryway
spaces. The original law imagined that these complexes would
remain affordable in perpetuity, but just a few years after the
program began, a new governor—
Nelson Rockefeller—introduced
an insidious element: after some
time, the owners could buy their
way out of the program. As a
result, of the roughly 105,000
homes created through the
Mitchell-Lama program, 45,841
rental apartments and 6,479
co-op apartments have left the
system.
SO FAR, ALL THESE social
housing programs have involved
the construction of new buildings and often the demolition of
old ones. But New York also has
a history of converting existing for-profit rental housing
into social housing. One of the
most predominant models is
the Housing Development Fund
Corporation.
HDFCs took off during a
moment of crisis for the city
and its real estate market:
the late 1970s and early ’80s,
when landlords were abandoning their properties in droves.
Many burned their buildings for
insurance money. Often those
who didn’t racked up tremendous tax debts, which put the
city in the position of foreclosing on them while its own coffers
were running low. Some of these
buildings were sold off to speculators. Others became squats.
Tenants around the city—and
particularly in rent-stabilized
buildings in hot spots of abandonment such as the South
Bronx, northern Manhattan,
Hell’s Kitchen, the Lower East
Side, Williamsburg, and Central
Brooklyn—organized and
demanded that the buildings be
legally turned over to them. And
in many cases, they were: today
there are about 1,100 HDFC
co-ops across the city, with
roughly 25,000 apartments.
The rules in HDFCs are
different from co-op to co-op,
and therefore their degree of
sociality varies wildly. Some
remain very cheap to buy into,
are serious about buyers income
caps, and are operated with a
commitment to democratic
self-governance. Others sell for
nearly market rate to voluntarily unemployed trust fund
kids or look the other way when
cooperators turn their apartments into permanent Airbnbs.
But in the best examples,
HDFCs demonstrate the possibility of transforming antisocial
housing into social housing,
giving hope to tenant activists
The social
housing
we have needs
more support
in order
to survive.
The antisocial
housing we
have is driving
residents into
homelessness,
debt, or
deprivation.
Fewer and
fewer among
us have faith
in the
status quo.
who want to seriously pursue
conversions and acquisitions in
addition to new construction.
Architecturally, most
HDFCs are indistinguishable
from the contemporaneous
housing that surrounds them.
On a block of tenement town
houses in neighborhoods (like
my Hell’s Kitchen) with lots of
HDFCs, there may be no visual
markers whatsoever to distinguish social from antisocial
housing. This reflects one of the
most exciting—but also in some
ways conservative—aspects
of social housing programs
premised on converting existing structures: They are made of
the stuff of the city as we know
it already. They do not seek to
transform the built environment
so much as the social relations
within it. In his book about life
on my exact street, Urbanism
Without Guarantees, geographer
Christian Anderson compares
the way residents of two similar
tenements dealt with a common
New York City scourge: bed
bugs. A renter had to appeal to
her landlord, who wanted to do
as little as possible to appease
the complainer and as a result
dealt with the problem (poorly)
in only the one apartment. The
NYRA #38
social housing cooperator, however, got the
board not only to ameliorate the problem in
the home in question but also to prevent it
from spreading to the entire building. Both,
in a sense, are organizing problems for the
residents, but the HDFC offers more possibilities for holistic action.
Alongside HDFCs (and sometimes in
combination with them), New Yorkers have
used two other tools to pursue social housing
conversions: community land trusts (CLTs)
and mutual housing associations (MHAs).
Of all the forms of social housing present in
New York City, perhaps none of the forms
command as much activist enthusiasm
today as the CLT.
Though the form traces back to the
southern civil rights movement, and
although other forms of land trusts have
been in place in New York for a long time,
the housing-focused urban CLT came to
the city through tenant organizing in the
Cooper Square section of the Lower East
Side. In the 1960s, residents rallied against
urban renewal demolition of their homes and
replacement with more expensive housing
(in this case including social cooperatives
most residents couldn’t afford). As narrated
in the recent documentary Rabble Rousers,
Cooper Square organizers first demanded
that public housing be built on a nearby
vacant lot. Once the housing went up, residents of the worst buildings in the area could
move into the new housing. Their old buildings would be torn down, and the process
could repeat on the new site. For a variety
of reasons, this didn’t happen. So the activists pivoted to a new strategy: turning the
existing buildings over to an MHA (a form of
nonprofit ownership in which tenants form
the majority of the board); getting money
from the city (in part from the construction of high-end housing elsewhere, in part
from standard capital and operating subsidies) to renovate the buildings; putting the
land beneath them into common ownership
through a separate entity—the CLT; and
converting the buildings into limited-equity cooperatives. It’s a wildly complicated
set of maneuvers, but the key points are that
the housing is decommodified and managed
under resident control; the land is decommodified and managed under the control of
a different nonprofit, with tenant participation but broader community input; and
neither party can take action without the
other, locking in affordability and sociality
in one corner of the Lower East Side.
For a while, Cooper Square was one of
the only residential CLT/MHAs in the city.
Now there are dozens in neighborhoods
across the five boroughs. Most of them are
aspirational, organizing people to be ready
to take over land. A few, however, already
have buildings under their belts. The East
Harlem/El Barrio CLT took over a set of
buildings that the city had long held and is
working on repairs and renovations. Meanwhile, the Interboro Community Land
Trust—a project of larger and more established nonprofits with an interest in CLTs,
including the Mutual Housing Association of New York (MHANY, which grew out
of a movement of organized squatters in
East New York and is now one of the largest nonprofit owners and developers in the
city), Habitat for Humanity (Jimmy Carter’s
postpresidential project), and the Center for
NYC Neighborhoods (a nonprofit that was
formed with city support to deal with the
effects of the 2008 financial crisis on homeowners). Interboro has focused on small
sites—including single-family homes that
have gone into foreclosure—but is growing, with new projects initiated by Habitat
putting their land into the CLT.
Like HDFCs, housing that’s in a CLT
in New York City is usually indistinguish-
able from housing that’s not. Though we
could build new social housing on top of
CLT-owned land, our city’s CLTs have
mostly been used as tools to preserve affordability in existing buildings and expand
resident democracy. While the external
architecture might not change much, the
culture of a place often does. The Cooper
Square CLT, for example, sponsors the
Fourth Street Arts Block, a stretch that
includes several experimental performance
spaces and galleries that likely couldn’t
survive without discounted rents. The institutions on the block often support the work
of local artists and do so without raising the
property values and rents of those who live
above them. There is a palpably different
feeling on that block than on many of those
that surround it, which are increasingly
corporate and inhospitable. It’s too soon to
measure such an impact in El Barrio and
other CLT sites, but it bodes the possibility
of social development and preservation at a
scale larger than the building.
Counting all the models listed above,
New York City has roughly 311,000 homes
that could be considered some form of social
housing, out of a total of 3,644,000 units. By
that rough estimate, then, under 9 percent
of the city’s housing stock is social housing, and 91 percent is not. Compared with
other US cities, that’s a lot; compared with
cities known for their social housing, like
Singapore or Vienna, it is not. Most of New
York City’s residents live in housing that
ranges from mansions and luxury condos on
the antisocial end of the spectrum to rent
regulated or subsidized private apartments
closer to the social side. As a direct result of
that fact, most New Yorkers can’t afford the
housing they’ve got, and more than 100,000
are living in the city’s shelter archipelago.
A lot of New York’s public housing is in
rough shape, in terms of both physical and
fiscal distress, and there is a tremendous
amount of pressure—both from the federal
government and from various quarters of
the real estate industry—to privatize it.
Some Mitchell-Lama cooperatives are being
pushed by city government to convert to
HDFCs, which would not constitute privatization but would shift them from being
deeply decommodified, zero-equity cooperatives into somewhat more commodified,
limited-equity co-ops and, in the process,
raise purchasing prices for future residents. Meanwhile, though many HDFCs
are well-functioning and stable, others face
crises of either poor building conditions,
limited cash reserves, or both. The same
condition faces the city’s remaining stock
of labor-built limited equity cooperatives.
The Amalgamated Housing Co-operative
in The Bronx is approaching its centenary,
but last year its board had to beg the state
government for support to keep it viable as
affordable housing. Rent stabilized housing—which is not a form of social housing
in and of itself but offers the opportunity
for tenants to organize and the potential
for tenant takeovers—is under attack from
landlords crying poverty and politicians
buying their bullshit.
In other words, the situation is not
stable. The social housing we have needs
more support in order to survive. The antisocial housing we have is driving residents into
homelessness, debt, or deprivation. Fewer
and fewer among us have faith in the status
quo.
WHILE EXISTING SOCIAL HOUSING
faces serious challenges, the movement to
produce more of it is stronger than it has
been in decades. Producing more social
housing—both through preservation of the
existing stock and acquiring and developing new housing—is on the agenda of several
REPORTAGE: THE SOCIAL HOUSING QUESTION
important groups in the state. Housing
Justice for All, a coalition of organizations
representing tenants and homeless New
Yorkers across the state, has social housing
as one of its core demands. The Democratic
Socialists of America put social housing in
both its New York and national planks. Even
the city’s primary YIMBY organization,
Open New York, included social housing in
its 2023 legislative agenda. Several elected
officials at the city and state levels have
backed the cause, including the city’s comptroller and public advocate and various city
council members, state assembly members,
and state senators. That’s a pretty big tent,
but it’s not yet enough to secure a program.
There isn’t yet a consensus around what
kind of social housing program to pursue,
and were there one, it would be tough for a
new program to take off without the support
of either the governor or the mayor, who
both favor private production over social
housing as their solutions to the housing
crisis.
At this point, there are two major models
being discussed by New York housing activists, which could be pursued solo or in
tandem. Both build on existing vehicles but
would require new public actions. Both also
contain significant internal contradictions,
which their supporters and detractors are
already debating.
The first model is new construction, or
building the kind of housing the market will
not provide. Depending on who is proposing
As a
geographer and
an urban
planner working
in the housing
movement, I often
find myself
dwelling on the
problem of
where social
housing might be
built. In a city
without a ton of
empty space,
with a bad history
of urban renewal,
with a diminished
stock of publicly
owned land,
and with rising sea
levels all
around us, this
is no simple
question.
9
it, the resulting projects could
combine some of the features
of public housing (public
ownership, elected tenant leadership, deep affordability) with
some of the features of Mitchell-Lama co-ops, HDFCs, and
CLTs (greater resident control)
and some of the features of
mixed-income housing (for some
supporters to combat segregation, for others to bring in
more rent money, and for all
to build a broad political base
for the housing). This housing
could comprise public rentals or resident-owned co-ops
or a combination of the two. It
could take the form of anything
from towers in the park to town
houses or even single-family
homes in some parts of the state.
Such projects could be
conceived and managed by New
York’s many existing housing
agencies and authorities—
such as local public housing
authorities (NYCHA in New
York City), the city’s housing
agency (Housing Preservation
and Development), the state’s
housing agency (Homes and
Community Renewal), or the
state’s catchall public development authority (Empire State
Development)—or the national
housing agency (HUD). Alternately, New York City or New
York State could create a
new public agency or authority whose sole and explicit
mission would be to produce
social housing. There is a city
council bill (Intro 0932, sponsored by Sandy Nurse) that, if
passed, will mandate the city’s
agencies to study the feasibility of establishing a new social
housing agency. There is also
work underway to draft legislation that would create a
state-level social housing development authority, which could
have both the broad powers of a
public authority (like the ability to acquire land and override
zoning) and the representative
function of an elective agency
(a board that includes a major
role for tenants and workers).
In addition to public entities,
there are a large number of
private, “mission driven” institutions like nonprofit housing
developers and community-development financial institutions
that could play a supportive role,
depending on how the model is
crafted.
Now is not the first time New
Yorkers have demanded that
the state create a social housing development authority. In
fact, the state did create one
in the late 1960s, in large part
in response to the civil rights
movement’s housing demands.
The Urban Development Corporation (UDC) had broad powers
to build social housing across
the state, including the power to
override local zoning and issue
its own bonds. It was responsible for 33,000 homes across
the state, including co-ops
and rentals at small and large
scales, from one-off developments to much of Roosevelt
10
Island. But after eight years of
success in building social housing, the authority was blocked
from confronting some of the
most trenchant suburban segregationists and eventually had
its work diverted from building social housing to the most
dystopic form of housing: prisons. It was then absorbed into
the larger Empire State Development, which has functioned
as a gubernatorial black box for
favored private development
projects. Many New Yorkers
don’t know this history at all;
others know it but believe we
can repeat the best parts of the
UDC legacy while preventing the
worst parts from being repeated.
To do so will require not just
care in the crafting of new policy,
but a large, ongoing, and politically engaged movement, with
adherents both inside state
government and anchoring
parties and coalitions that will
keep a close eye on the authority
and push back against mission
creep.
Another issue that often
arises is whether new social
housing should be targeted or
universal—whether it should
house those least served by
the current housing system or
whether it should aim to house
everybody, from the poor to
the well-off. This may be a false
dichotomy, as there’s plenty
of room in between the two
extremes, but different camps
are organizing toward different and sometimes mutually
exclusive visions. All our existing social models are means
tested, to varying degrees.
New social housing could operate like public housing, which is
mostly available for those the
city calls “extremely and very
low income,” thus ensuring that
those most excluded from the
current housing market are
prioritized in the new alternative. But it could also operate
more like private housing, with
some percentage designated as
“affordable” and the rest renting
at market rates, thus allowing for more independence from
often-insufficient public operating revenue streams. Both sides
have their supporters, but many
activists fall somewhere in the
middle, seeing a role for both—
something like the reverse of
inclusionary housing, in which
the bulk of homes would be
low-cost rentals or co-ops for
low-income households, while
a smaller portion would be for
people making and paying more.
This question has roiled social
housing campaigns in other
places (no surprise, California
is the most visible and vitriolic
example) and won’t be easy to
resolve here either.
As a geographer and an
urban planner working in the
housing movement, I often find
myself dwelling on the problem
of where social housing might be
built. In a city without a ton of
empty space, with a bad history
of urban renewal, with a diminished stock of publicly owned
land, and with rising sea levels
all around us, this is no simple
question. It’s easy to say, “We’ll
eminent domain Billionaire’s
Row,” or something on that
order, but pulling that off would
mean having much more power
and money than the left has ever
had in this city or state, so without a plan to attain that power
it’s not much of an answer.
Considering this program on
a state rather than a city level
helps to some extent, but it
would be hard to tell tenants
in Crown Heights that beautiful new social housing was being
built for them in Syracuse.
Another way to answer the
“where” question, though, is
“wherever you already live.”
This model would get the city
back into the business of social
housing conversions, but under
drastically different market
conditions than in the heyday
of tax foreclosures and HDFC
conversions. As described in a
2022 report by Oksana Mironova, Celeste Hornbach, Jacob
Udell, and me entitled Pathways to Social Housing in New
York, the concept would be to
simultaneously strengthen
tenants’ rights, ramp up housing code enforcement, raise
revenue through progressive
taxation and fees, and expand
opportunities for public and
community control of land and
buildings. Taken together, these
four streams could combine to
squeeze out exploitive landlords while building up state and
movement power to take control
of housing.
Because there is a history
of these kinds of practices in
New York City—my own home
is part of its legacy—there are
some institutional mechanisms
already in place. There are public
programs at the city level to buy
buildings, but they are all underfunded and are not necessarily
geared toward resident management. There are also ways for
tenants to sue for receivership
if their building is falling apart,
but there is no clear mechanism to transition from there
into full and permanent social
ownership. Part of the work,
then, is expanding current practices and programs. The other
part is to pass new laws like the
Tenant Opportunity to Purchase
Act, which would kick in when
a rental building goes up for
sale and would allow tenants
to either buy the building and
turn it into a social cooperative
or to name a preferred buyer,
which could be a CLT, MHA, or
even a public housing authority.
Relatedly, the city must permanently abolish the practice of
selling liens on tax-delinquent
land and housing and instead
reinstitute public foreclosure
with preferential paths for CLT
acquisitions.
To some extent, this is an
easier path forward than new
construction. Organizers can
work with tenants in existing
buildings to build support for
an acquisition strategy and a
SO YOU WANT TO BUILD
MASS SOCIAL HOUSING.
FIRST ASK YOURSELF
THESE QUESTIONS:
⬤WHAT MODELS OF SOCIAL
HOUSING ARE THERE?
Should we build new housing or
convert existing buildings? Do we
want to see public rentals, limited-equity co-ops, or something
else?
⬤WHERE WILL YOU PUT THE
HOUSING?
In a city without a lot of open
space, surrounded by rising tides,
and with a bad history of both
urban renewal and quasi-suburban exclusion, how can we make
social housing siting equitable and
ubiquitous?
⬤WHO WILL FUND/RUN IT?
Should it be built and run by the
government? If so, can the existing institutions handle it, or do we
need to build a new social housing
authority? Should there be a role
for nonprofits or unions?
⬤WHEN CAN WE GET IT?
Is new mass social housing something the left can pursue and
win today, or is it something we
must build toward over a longer
timescale?
⬤HOW CAN WE GET IT DONE?
What kind of a state would we
need to win? Do we need new
executives (president, governor,
or mayor), or can we secure it with
progressive legislators?
conversion model, and elected
officials can help deliver social
housing to voters who already
live in their districts. But it also
presents significant challenges,
distinct from those of the new
construction model.
First, not all the housing that exists is housing that
anyone should be living in.
Much of the time, social housing conversions would take place
in heavily exploited rent-stabilized buildings that landlords
have milked for rents and sold
for elevated prices again and
again, leaving building systems
in disrepair and tenants at
their wits’ ends. This situation is reminiscent of the one
that produced the HDFCs,
and some buildings absorbed
into that program never were
quite able to recover from their
distress. This may be even more
of a problem outside New York
City, where the housing stock
in many severely disinvested
cities tends to be in even worse
condition. It’s not always clear
tenants would want to remain in
their homes if new social housing construction were a serious
alternative.
NYRA #38
Second, the program could be a victim
of its own success. Since the model is built
on taking taxed for-profit housing off the
market and replacing it with tax-exempt
social housing, and given that real estate
taxes make up over 40 percent of the city’s
annual revenues, the model could financially
implode without some other major source
of progressive taxation to make up for the
lost revenue. The state of New York controls
most decisions around tax policy in New
York City, so any solution would have to have
both city and state buy-in.
Nonetheless, conversions probably present a less daunting form of social housing
production. Bills to enable these conversions—like the Tenant Opportunity to
Purchase Act at the state level and the
Community Opportunity to Purchase Act
at the city level—have already been introduced, and vehicles (albeit imperfect)
already exist to fund them. But it would be
a mistake to forego the construction model
altogether. Doing so would relegate responsibility for new housing construction to
market actors who have already shown their
unwillingness or inability to build housing
most New Yorkers can access. Just as importantly, focusing exclusively on conversions
would leave New Yorkers in the conservative
position of solely preserving the housing we
have rather than envisioning and building
new spaces for the public good. None of it is
easy, but our best hope is to do it all.
THE DEEPER WE GO WITH large-scale
proposals for social housing, the more questions arise. This, however, is a strength,
not a weakness, of the pursuit. No one
can seriously think it will be simple or
straightforward to create large amounts of
decommodified, socially equitable, decarbonized, resident controlled housing in the
context of hypercommodified housing and
a mature real estate state and a worsening
climate catastrophe. Anyone peddling one
neat trick to resolve the housing question
is a huckster marketing an alluring illusion.
If we’re confronting these contradictions, it
means we’re taking seriously the proposition
of mass social housing.
Some aspects of social housing are
clearer to us than others. We have some idea
of what decommodification means, even
if it’s hard to achieve. We have some idea
of what social equality means, even if it’s
hard to achieve. We have some idea of what
decarbonization means, even if it’s hard to
achieve. But we have a far weaker grasp of
what resident control really means in practice.
The answer is perhaps clearest in co-op
models, where residents vote for a board and
take votes on certain other major matters.
There are plenty of examples of co-op boards
running amok, in both social and marketrate housing, but at least in the co-op
system, there is an appeal to democracy: if
board members have violated the co-op’s
rules or the government’s laws, they can be
deposed, and shareholders have a chance to
elect new members whenever regular elections are held.
Resident control in rental buildings
is somewhat less defined. Public housing
residents are legally entitled to elected leadership, which can speak to management on
issues of concern to tenants. Many privately
owned buildings have tenant associations
with elected leadership as well. But resident leaders in rental housing usually face
a structural problem: They often do not
have the money or power to do what their
residents need. The Citywide Council of
Presidents—New York City’s body of elected
public housing resident leaders—can lobby
congress and the president for more funding through the HUD budget, but it cannot
itself secure the money needed to address
constituents’ most pressing problems. In an
MHA, at least, elected tenant leaders form
the majority of the association’s governing
board, giving renters a real leadership position. But there, too, control over the board
does not guarantee access to adequate funding, which can put tenant leaders in the
position of having to go back to their neighbors and explain why they cannot address
the problems at hand.
Resident democracy also raises issues
beyond the scale of the building or the
housing complex. Sometimes residents’ individual desires conflict with the needs of the
system as a whole. The region may need to
prioritize decarbonization, but some residents may want to use their democratic
rights to assert their preference for fossil
fuel–based heating and cooling systems in
their respective buildings. The region may
need more social housing, but some residents may say there’s enough (or too much)
in their town already. This is not a hypothetical in New York City; consider, for
example, the decades-long struggle around
the Seward Park Urban Renewal Area on
the Lower East Side and the actions of residents in union-built co-ops to prevent the
construction of more public housing in an
area that, they argued, already had enough.
These kinds of site fights demonstrate
the tension between two ideals commonly
held on the housing left—community control
and comprehensive planning. In theory,
comprehensive planning should be grounded
in community planning, but in practice one
might have to bend to the other. Many on the
left feel that low-income areas facing disinvestment or gentrification should get to plan
for themselves what kind of social housing
will be produced in their area. That level of
control would be necessary to build trust
and support for the program among those
who need it most, but it might result in less
housing getting built than some planners
desire and the city or state as a whole needs.
Meanwhile, many on the left also believe
that any social housing authority should
have the power to override local zoning laws
and land use regulations. That power would
be necessary to build much-needed social
housing in low-density, high-income, transit-served areas in the city and especially in
its suburbs, but it would mean limiting those
communities’ control over their surroundings. To put these two values together, we
would need to design a system that differentiates between areas with uneven levels of
power. Such a system is possible to plan but
can be difficult to implement on the ground,
where the line between one type of community and another is often blurrier than we
imagine and where these power dynamics
shift over time.
Any attempt to grapple with these
tensions must take place within social movements, not just in academic or policy circles.
Early labor cooperatives, public housing,
HDFCs, and CLTs all came out of movement
contexts, but in many cases the housing models have, over time, become more
removed from any active political project.
Without a strong movement attached to the
housing, individual residents can become
disillusioned with any social model and seek
to maximize their personal profits as homeowners through privatization or may come
to believe in the mainstream notion that
governments are inherently bad developers
and landlords. Many of the most successful social housing models around the world
are closely tied to labor movements and left
parties, which can help build a political base
and armature around the housing, rather
than using the housing to stand in for a
political program.
The kind of state that can equitably and
REPORTAGE: THE SOCIAL HOUSING QUESTION
efficiently parse out that kind of program
while also competently executing the functions of social housing production and
management is, to say the least, not the
kind of state we have today. I often need to
remind myself of the difference between
“the state” in the abstract and “this state”
we have today. The state could do all of the
things discussed here—seize property from
bad landlords, build social housing in the
suburbs. This state as we know it today
(in New York City, New York State, or the
United States of America) will do none of
them.
So what would it take to transform the
latter state into the former? Social democrats often look to examples like Vienna
to show that it doesn’t necessarily take a
revolution to win the kind of state that can
support a mass social housing program. That
city’s Social Democratic Party has remained
popular in large part because of the success
of its majoritarian social housing program,
which 80 percent of city residents qualify
for and 60 percent choose to live in. But the
Red Vienna program, which established this
paradigm starting in 1918, was damn close to
a revolutionary outcome, coming into existence only after World War I, the fall of the
Austro-Hungarian Empire and the Habsburg
monarchy, the rise of socialist movements
throughout the continent and around the
world, and the country’s first-ever popular election. It might have been an electoral
achievement, but it was an election that
looked pretty different than anything like
New York’s next mayoral or gubernatorial
races. It was then overthrown by one of the
most horrifyingly violent regimes in human
history, only to be moderately rebuilt after
the Second World War. This is not just the
stuff of door knocking and persuasion. On
glum days—and to be honest, that’s most of
them for me of late—it’s hard to see how the
political repertoire we’ve developed in New
York might lead to the scale of change capable of delivering the mass social housing we
need.
It’s no shortcoming that the New York
housing left has no definitive solutions to
the quandaries raised by the social housing question, which, in its basic parameters,
isn’t so different from that posed by Friedrich Engels in his famous 1872 pamphlet The
Housing Question. Contradiction is intrinsic to capitalist society, no less so today than
150 years ago. Perhaps hewing too closely
to historical models of change, however, is
itself a liability. What we need is a theory of
the way things are and the way we want them
to be; a grasp of how these ideas have worked
in past cycles of struggle; a willingness to
look closely at the present conjuncture
and understand the complexities of the
balance of forces; and the determination to
go forward with campaigns that will have to
be revised and rerun many times over. This
may not be a satisfying answer, let alone an
expedient one, but it’s the only honest one. ⬤
Samuel Stein is the author of Capital City:
Gentrification and the Real Estate State. A few years
ago, he wasn’t so sure about the term social housing,
but look at him now!
11