«Մասնակից:Լիան Երիցյան/Ավազարկղ1»–ի խմբագրումների տարբերություն
No edit summary |
|||
Տող 1. | Տող 1. | ||
'''Market socialism''' is a type of [[economic system]] involving [[social ownership]] of the [[means of production]] within the framework of a [[market economy]]. Various models for such a system exist, usually involving [[Cooperative|cooperative enterprises]] and sometimes a mix that includes [[Public enterprise|public]] or [[private enterprises]].<ref>{{Cite book |last1=Schweickart |first1=David |title=Market Socialism: The Debate Among Socialists |last2=Lawler |first2=James |last3=Tickten |first3=Hillel |last4=Ollman |first4=Bertell |publisher=[[Taylor & Francis]] |date=2016-04-22 |pages=105 |quote=....it is important to realize that the school of thinking calls itself "market socialism" is further divisible along three different lines: (1) whether its goal, market socialism, involves only worker-owned enterprises, or a mix of enterprises some worker-owned, some privately-owned, some nationalized, etc. (2) whether market socialism will eventually by followed by communism...}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book |last=Corneo |first=Giacomo |title=Is Capitalism Obsolete? A Journey through Alternative Economic Systems |publisher=[[Harvard University Press]] |year=2017 |location=Cambridge, MA |pages=192–197}}</ref> In contrast to the majority of historic [[List of socialist states|socialist economies]], which have substituted the market mechanism for some form of [[Planned economy|economic planning]], market socialists wish to retain the use of [[supply and demand]] signals to guide the allocation of [[capital good]]s and the means of production.<ref>{{cite book |last=O'Hara |first=Phillip |title=Encyclopedia of Political Economy |volume=2 |publisher=[[Routledge]] |date=September 2000 |isbn=978-0415241878 |page=71 |quote=Market socialism is the general designation for a number of models of economic systems. On the one hand, the market mechanism is utilized to distribute economic output, to organize production and to allocate factor inputs. On the other hand, the economic surplus accrues to society at large rather than to a class of private (capitalist) owners, through some form of collective, public or social ownership of capital.}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Buchanan |first=Alan E. |year=1985 |title=Ethics, Efficiency and the Market |publisher=[[Oxford University Press]] |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=dqcoCqFrZFYC&q=ethics,efficiency+and+the+market+Two.types.of.market.socialism&pg=PA104 |pages=104–105 |isbn=978-0-8476-7396-4}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Gregory |first1=Paul R. |last2=Stuart |first2=Robert C. |year=2003 |title=Comparing Economic Systems in the Twenty-First Century |pages=142 |quote="It is an economic system that combines social ownership of capital with market allocation of capital...The state owns the means of production, and returns accrue to society at large." |isbn=0-618-26181-8}}</ref> Under such a system, depending on whether socially owned firms are [[State ownership|state-owned]] or operated as [[worker cooperative]]s, profits may variously be used to directly remunerate employees, accrue to society at large as the source of [[public finance]], or be distributed amongst the population in a [[social dividend]].<ref name="Social Dividend versus Basic Income Guarantee in Market Socialism, 2004">{{cite journal |url=https://www.researchgate.net/publication/5172406 |title=Social Dividend Versus Basic Income Guarantee in Market Socialism |last=Marangos |first=John |year=2004 |journal=[[International Journal of Political Economy]] |volume=34 |issue=3 |pages=20–40 |doi=10.1080/08911916.2004.11042930 |jstor=40470892 |s2cid=153267388}}</ref> |
|||
'''Ալֆրեդո Ֆելիքս Քրիստիանի Բուրկարդ''' ({{lang-es|Alfredo Félix Cristiani Burkard}}, {{ԱԾ}}), [[սալվադոր|սալվադորցի]] գործարար, քաղաքական և պետական գործիչ, 1989-1994 թվականներին Սալվադորի նախագահ: Ազգայնական հանրապետական դաշինք [[Աջեր|աջակողմյան]] կուսակցության ղեկավարներից մեկը։ [[Ռոբերտո դ'Օբյուսոն]]ի ուղեկիցն ու իրավահաջորդը: Ալֆրեդո Քրիստիանիի նախագահության ընթացքում համաձայնություն է ձեռք բերվել Սալվադորում քաղաքացիական պատերազմը դադարեցնելու և [[Նեոլիբերալիզմ|նեոլիբերալ]] տնտեսական բարեփոխումներ իրականացնելու վերաբերյալ: Պահպանել է քաղաքական ազդեցությունը նախագահի պաշտոնը թողնելուց հետո։ Հայտնի է եղել նաև որպես խոշոր գործարար։ |
|||
Market socialism can be distinguished from the concept of the [[mixed economy]] because most models of market socialism propose complete and self-regulating systems, unlike the mixed economy.<ref>{{cite book |url=https://www.sup.org/books/title/?id=21002 |last=Bockman |first=Johanna |title=Markets in the name of Socialism: The Left-Wing origins of Neoliberalism |publisher=Stanford University Press |year=2011 |isbn=978-0-8047-7566-3 |access-date=2020-12-25 |archive-date=2020-11-28 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20201128072149/https://www.sup.org/books/title/?id=21002 |url-status=live }}</ref> While social democracy aims to achieve greater [[economic stability]] and equality through policy measures such as taxes, subsidies, and social welfare programs, market socialism aims to achieve similar goals through changing patterns of enterprise ownership and management.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Roosevelt III |first1=Franklin Delano |author1-link=Franklin Delano Roosevelt III |first2=David |last2=Belkin |title=Why Market Socialism? |publisher=[[M.E. Sharpe, Inc.]] |year=1994 |isbn=978-1-56324-465-0 |page=314 |quote=Social democracy achieves greater egalitarianism via ex post government taxes and subsidies, where market socialism does so via ex ante changes in patterns of enterprise ownership. |title-link=Why Market Socialism?}}</ref> |
|||
== Ծագում և բիզնես == |
|||
Ծնվել է [[Իտալիա|իտալական]] ծագումով հարուստ հողատիրոջ ընտանիքում<ref>{{Cite web |url=http://www.comune.bagnaria.pv.it/storia-e-personaggi/2-pagine-sito/50-alfredo-cristiani |title=Alfredo Cristiani |access-date=2018-05-24 |archive-date=2018-05-25 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180525062246/http://www.comune.bagnaria.pv.it/storia-e-personaggi/2-pagine-sito/50-alfredo-cristiani |deadlink=no }}</ref>: Ֆելիքս Քրիստիանին՝ Ալֆրեդո Կրիշտիանու հայրը, եղել է մշակող սուրճ և զբաղվել խոշոր ագրոբիզնեսով։ Մարգո Բուրկարդ դե Կրիստիանին՝ Ալֆրեդո Կրիստիանիի մայրը, սերել է [[Շվեյցարացիներ|շվեյցարացի]] ներգաղթյալների ընտանիքից։ |
|||
Though the term "market socialism" only emerged in the 1920s during the [[socialist calculation debate]],<ref name="Steele 177">{{cite book |last=Steele |first=David Ramsay |title=From Marx to Mises: Post Capitalist Society and the Challenge of Economic Calculation |date=September 1999 |publisher=Open Court |isbn=978-0875484495 |page=177 |quote=It was in the early 1920s that the expression 'market socialism' (''marktsozialismus'') became commonplace. A special term was considered necessary to distinguish those socialists prepared to accept some role for factor markets from the now mainstream socialists who were not. |author-link=David Ramsay Steele}}</ref> a number of [[pre-Marx socialists]], including the [[Ricardian socialist]] economists and [[Mutualism (economic theory)|mutualist]] philosophers, conceived of socialism as a natural development of the market principles of [[classical economics]], and proposed the creation of co-operative enterprises to compete in a [[free-market]] economy. The aim of such proposals was to eliminate exploitation by allowing individuals to receive the [[To each according to his contribution|full product of their labor]], while removing the market-distorting effects of concentrating ownership and wealth in the hands of a small class of [[private property]] owners.<ref>{{cite book |last=McNally |first=David |title=Against the Market: Political Economy, Market Socialism and the Marxist Critique |publisher=[[Verso Books]] |date=1993 |isbn=978-0-86091-606-2 |page=44 |quote=[...] [B]y the 1820s, 'Smithian' apologists for industrial capitalism confronted 'Smithian' socialists in a vigorous, and often venomous, debate over political economy.}}</ref> |
|||
Ալֆրեդո Քրիստիանին իր մանկությունն ու պատանեկությունն անց է կացրել արտոնյալ պայմաններում։ Սովորել է հեղինակավոր դպրոցում, զբաղվել է սպորտով՝ բասկետբոլով, սքվոշով, այնուհետև մոտոարշավով և սլաներիզմով<ref name=acb>{{Cite web |url=http://biography.yourdictionary.com/alfredo-cristiani |title=Alfredo Cristiani Facts |access-date=2018-05-24 |archive-date=2017-07-06 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170706210250/http://biography.yourdictionary.com/alfredo-cristiani |deadlink=no }}</ref>: Բարձրագույն կրթությունը ստացել Է [[Ամերիկայի Միացյալ Նահանգներ|ԱՄՆ]] [[Ջորջթաունի համալսարան]]ում։ Մասնագիտությամբ բիզնես ադմինիստրատոր է եղել: |
|||
Although sometimes described as "market socialism",<ref>{{cite book |last=Stiglitz |first=Joseph E. |title=Whither Socialism? |publisher=[[MIT Press]] |year=1996 |isbn=9780262691826 |location=Cambridge, MA}}</ref> the [[Lange model]] is a form of market simulated planning where a central planning board allocates investment and capital goods by simulating factor market transactions, while markets allocate labor and consumer goods. The system was devised by [[socialist economics|socialist economists]] who believed that a socialist economy could neither function on the basis of [[Calculation in kind|calculation in natural units]] nor through solving a system of simultaneous equations for economic coordination.<ref>{{cite book |last=Roemer |first=John |title=A Future for Socialism |date=1 January 1994 |publisher=[[Harvard University Press]] |isbn=978-0674339460 |page=28 |quote=The first stage was marked by the realization by socialists that prices must be used for economic calculation under socialism; accounting in some kind of 'natural unit,' such as the amount of energy or labor commodities embodied, simply would not work. The second stage was characterized by the view that it would be possible to calculate the prices at which general equilibrium would be reached in a socialist economy by solving a complicated system of simultaneous equations [...]. The third stage was marked by the realization, by Lange and others, that markets would indeed be required to find the socialist equilibrium [...].}}</ref><ref name="Steele 177"/> |
|||
Վերադառնալով Սալվադոր՝ Ալֆրեդո Կրիստիանին սկսել է աշխատել ընտանեկան բիզնեսում։ Զբաղվել է բիզնեսով [[սուրճ]]ի, [[Բամբակենի|բամբակ]]ի և [[Դեղագործություն|դեղագործության]] ոլորտներում։ Հիմնադրել է «Semillas Cristiani Burkard» (SCB) առևտրային ընկերությունը։ Նա հավատարիմ է եղել [[Աջեր|աջակողմյան]] [[Պահպանողականություն|պահպանողական]] հայացքներին, սակայն քաղաքական գործունեության նկատմամբ հետաքրքրություն չի ցուցաբերել<ref name=acb1>{{Cite web |url=https://www.cidob.org/biografias_lideres_politicos/america_central_y_caribe/el_salvador/alfredo_cristiani_burkard |title=Alfredo Cristiani Burkard. Biografía |access-date=2018-05-24 |archive-date=2017-04-28 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170428041653/http://www.cidob.org/biografias_lideres_politicos/america_central_y_caribe/el_salvador/alfredo_cristiani_burkard |deadlink=no }}</ref>: |
|||
Real-world attempts to create market socialist economies have only partially implemented the measures envisioned by its theorists, but the term has sometimes been used to describe the results of various attempts at [[Economic liberalization|liberalization]] in the [[Eastern Bloc]] including [[New Economic Mechanism|Hungary's New Economic Mechanism]], the [[Economy of the Socialist Federal Republic of Yugoslavia|economy of Yugoslavia]], [[Perestroika]], and the [[Chinese economic reform|economic reforms of China]] as well as [[Vladimir Lenin|Lenin]]'s [[New Economic Policy]].<ref>{{Cite web |last=Ackerman |first=Seth |title=The Forgotten Vision of Market Socialism |url=https://www.ineteconomics.org/perspectives/blog/the-forgotten-vision-of-market-socialism |access-date=2023-08-21 |website=Institute for New Economic Thinking |language=en |archive-date=2023-08-21 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230821194751/https://www.ineteconomics.org/perspectives/blog/the-forgotten-vision-of-market-socialism |url-status=live }}</ref> |
|||
== ԱՀԴ աջակողմյան քաղաքական գործիչ == |
|||
1979 թվականին սկսվել է [[Սալվադոր]]ի քաղաքացիական պատերազմը։ Քաղաքական իրավիճակի կտրուկ խստացումը Ալֆրեդո Քրիստիանիին դրդել է զբաղվել քաղաքականությամբ։ Նա միացել է Ազգայնական հանրապետական դաշինք կուսակցությանը, որը ստեղծվել է ծայրահեղ աջակողմյան մահվան ջոկատների հրամանատար մայոր Ռոբերտո դ'Օբյուսոնի կողմից: Եղել է դ'Օբյուսոնի մտերիմ զինակիցը, փորձել է ընդօրինակել նրան ոճով և հռետորաբանությամբ: Ընդ որում, դիտորդները կտրուկ հակադրություն են արձանագրել չափավոր և ոչ խարիզմատիկ Քրիստիանիի և «մահվան էսկադրոնների» խառնվածքային առաջնորդի միջև: |
|||
== Theoretical history == |
|||
1984 թվականին Սալվադորում տեղի է ունեցել նախագահական ընտրություններ: ԱՀԴ-ից առաջադրված մայոր դ'Օբյուսոնը զիջել է քրիստոնեա-դեմոկրատական կուսակցության առաջնորդ Խոսե Նապոլեոն Դուարտային: Այդ ժամանակ [[Ֆարաբունդո մարտի ազգային ազատագրման ճակատ]]ի կոմունիստական կուսակցականիստական շարժման իշխանության գալն արդեն քիչ հավանական է եղել: |
|||
=== Classical economics === |
|||
The key theoretical basis for market socialism is the negation of the underlying expropriation of [[surplus value]] present in other [[modes of production]]. Socialist theories that favored the market date back to the [[Ricardian socialism|Ricardian socialists]] and [[Anarchist economics|anarchist economists]], who advocated a [[free market]] combined with [[public ownership]] or [[Mutualization|mutual ownership]] of the means of production. |
|||
Proponents of early market socialism include the [[Ricardian socialism|Ricardian socialist economists]], the classical liberal philosopher [[John Stuart Mill]] and the anarchist philosopher [[Pierre-Joseph Proudhon]]. These models of socialism entailed perfecting or improving the [[market mechanism]] and [[free price system]] by removing distortions caused by [[Exploitation of labour|exploitation]], [[private property]] and [[alienated labor]]. |
|||
Ընտրություններում ձախողումից հետո Ռոբերտո դ'Օբյուսոնը անցել է ԱՀԴ-ի պատվավոր նախագահի կարգավիճակին։ Կուսակցության ղեկավարի իր իրավահաջորդը Ռոբերտոն անվանել է Ալֆրեդո Քրիստիանին։ Միևնույն ժամանակ դ'Օբյուսոնը նշել է, որ նոր նախագահի «չափազանց քաղաքավարի» վարքագիծը բացասաբար կընկալվի բանակի սպաների կուսակցության դաշնակիցների կողմից: |
|||
This form of market socialism has been termed free-market socialism because it does not involve planners.<ref>{{cite book |title=Property and Prophets: the evolution of economic institutions and ideologies |first=E. K. |last=Hunt |date=20 November 2002 |publisher=[[M. E. Sharpe]] |isbn=978-0-7656-0609-9 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=fMGjVbg_mOAC&q=free.market.socialism&pg=PA72 |pages=72 |access-date=10 August 2021 |archive-date=8 February 2024 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208021152/https://books.google.com/books?id=fMGjVbg_mOAC&q=free.market.socialism&pg=PA72#v=snippet&q=free.market.socialism&f=false |url-status=live }}</ref><ref>{{cite web |url=http://mutualist.blogspot.com/2006/07/js-mill-market-socialist.html |title=J.S. Mill, Market Socialist |first=Kevin |last=Carson |date=16 July 2006 |work=Mutualist Blog: Free Market Anti-Capitalism |access-date=2 March 2016 |archive-date=6 March 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190306044351/http://mutualist.blogspot.com/2006/07/js-mill-market-socialist.html |url-status=live }}</ref> |
|||
<blockquote> |
|||
Քրիստիանին ԱՀԴ-ում «խորթ եղբայր» էր։ Նա միլիոնատեր ընտանիքից էր, բայց դա ղեկավար պաշտոն չապահովեց մայոր դ’Օբուսսոնի հիմնադրած կուսակցությունում<ref>{{Cite web |url=https://elfaro.net/es/201710/el_salvador/21035/Calder%C3%B3n-Sol-el-%E2%80%9Ctraidor%E2%80%9D-que-empuj%C3%B3-a-Arena-hacia-la-paz.htm |title=Calderón Sol: el «traidor» que empujó a Arena hacia la paz |access-date=2018-08-14 |archive-date=2018-07-01 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180701193913/https://elfaro.net/es/201710/el_salvador/21035/Calder%C3%B3n-Sol-el-%E2%80%9Ctraidor%E2%80%9D-que-empuj%C3%B3-a-Arena-hacia-la-paz.htm |deadlink=no }}</ref>: |
|||
</blockquote> |
|||
==== John Stuart Mill ==== |
|||
1988 թվականի խորհրդարանական ընտրություններում Ալֆրեդո Քրիստիանին ընտրվել է Օրենսդիր ժողովի պատգամավոր։ |
|||
Mill's early [[Philosophy and economics|economic philosophy]] was one of [[free market]]s that he moved toward a more socialist bent, adding chapters to his ''[[Principles of Political Economy]]'' in defence of a socialist outlook, and defending some socialist causes.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Mill |first1=John Stuart |author1-link=John Stuart Mill |editor1-last=Bentham |editor1-first=Jeremy |editor2-last=Ryan |editor2-first=Alan |title=Utilitarianism and other essays |publisher=[[Penguin Books]] |year=2004 |location=London |isbn=978-0-14-043272-5 |page=[https://archive.org/details/utilitarianismot00mill/page/11 11] |url-access=registration |url=https://archive.org/details/utilitarianismot00mill/page/11}}</ref> Within this revised work he also made the radical proposal that the whole wage system be abolished in favour of a co-operative wage system. Nonetheless, some of his views on the idea of flat taxation remained,<ref name="stanford">{{cite encyclopedia |editor-last=Wilson |editor-first=Fred |title=John Stuart Mill: Political Economy |encyclopedia=Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy |publisher=[[Stanford University]] |year=2007 |url=http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/mill/#PolEco |access-date=4 May 2009 |archive-date=6 January 2010 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100106122801/http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/mill/#PolEco |url-status=live }}</ref> albeit altered in the third edition of the ''Principles of Political Economy'' to reflect a concern for differentiating restrictions on [[unearned income]]s which he favoured; and those on earned incomes, which he did not favour.<ref name="principles online">{{cite web |url=http://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/mill-principles-of-political-economy-ashley-ed#lf0199_label_1109 |title=On The General Principles of Taxation, V.2.14 |last=Mill |first=John Stuart |author-link=John Stuart Mill |year=1852 |work=Principles of Political Economy |publisher=[Online Library of Liberty] |access-date=6 January 2013 |archive-date=7 May 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190507143352/https://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/mill-principles-of-political-economy-ashley-ed#lf0199_label_1109 |url-status=live }} (3rd edition; the passage about flat taxation was altered by the author in this edition, which is acknowledged in this online edition's footnote 8. This sentence replaced in the 3rd ed. a sentence of the original: "It is partial taxation, which is a mild form of robbery".</ref> |
|||
Mill's ''Principles'', first published in 1848, was one of the most widely read of all books on economics in the period.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Ekelund |first1=Robert B. Jr. |last2=Hébert |first2=Robert F. |title=A history of economic theory and method |edition=4th |publisher=Waveland Press |location=Long Grove, Illinois |year=1997 |isbn=978-1-57766-381-2 |page=172}}</ref> As [[Adam Smith]]'s ''[[The Wealth of Nations|Wealth of Nations]]'' had during an earlier period, Mill's ''Principles'' dominated economics teaching. In the case of [[Oxford University]], it was the standard text until 1919, when it was replaced by [[Alfred Marshall]]'s ''[[Principles of Economics (Marshall)|Principles of Economics]]''. |
|||
== Սալվադորի նախագահ == |
|||
In later editions of ''Principles of Political Economy'', Mill would argue that "as far as economic theory was concerned, there is nothing in principle in economic theory that precludes an economic order based on socialist policies".<ref name="stanford"/><ref>{{cite book |last=Baum |first=Bruce. |chapter=J. S. Mill and Liberal Socialism |editor1-last=Urbanati |editor1-first=Nadia |editor2-last=Zachars |editor2-first=Alex |year=2007 |title=J. S. Mill's Political Thought: A Bicentennial Reassessment |location=Cambridge |publisher=[[Cambridge University Press]] |quote="Mill, in contrast, advances a form of liberal democratic socialism for the enlargement of freedom as well as to realize social and distributive justice. He offers a powerful account of economic injustice and justice that is centered on his understanding of freedom and its conditions"}}</ref> |
|||
=== Ընտրություն=== |
|||
1989 թվականին [[Սալվադոր]]ում կրկին տեղի է ունեցել նախագահական ընտրություններ: Ալֆրեդո Քրիստիանիին առաջադրվել է ԱՀԴ կուսակցությունից։ Այդ ժամանակ ԱՀԴ-ի գաղափարախոսությունն ու քաղաքական կուրսը նկատելիորեն զարգացել էին աջակողմյան արմատականությունից ([[նեոֆաշիզմ]]ին մոտ) դեպի ազգային պահպանողականություն։ Քրիստիանիը քարոզարշավը վարել է քաղաքացիական պատերազմի դադարեցման և տնտեսության ազատականացման կարգախոսներով: Ընդ որում, նա խոստացել է ուժի մեջ թողնել հանրաճանաչ ագրարային բարեփոխման արդյունքները, որոնք իրականացրել են քրիստոնյա դեմոկրատները [[Խոսե Անտոնիո Մորալես Էրլիխ]]ի ղեկավարությամբ: |
|||
Mill also promoted substituting capitalist businesses with [[worker cooperatives]], writing: |
|||
Ալֆրեդո Քրիստիանին հաղթել է ՔԴԿ-ի թեկնածու Ֆիդել Չավես Մենային։ Քրիստիանիի օգտին քվեարկել է ընտրողների գրեթե 54 տոկոսը, Չավես Մենայի օգտին՝ մոտ 36,5 տոկոսը: Դա տպավորիչ ռևանշ է թվացել 1984 թվականի համար: 1989 թվականի հունիսի 1-ին Ալֆրեդո Քրիստիանին պաշտոնապես ստանձնել է Սալվադորի նախագահի պաշտոնը։ ԱՀԴ կուսակցությունն առաջին անգամ եկել է իշխանության: |
|||
<blockquote>The form of association, however, which if mankind continue to improve, must be expected in the end to predominate, is not that which can exist between a capitalist as chief, and work-people without a voice in the management, but the association of the labourers themselves on terms of equality, collectively owning the capital with which they carry on their operations and working under managers elected and removable by themselves.<ref>{{cite book |title=Principles of Political Economy with some of their Applications to Social Philosophy |url=http://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/101#Mill_0199_1342 |editor-first=William James |editor-last=Ashley |first=John Stuart |last=Mill |author-link=John Stuart Mill |location=London |publisher=Longmans, Green and Co. |year=1909 |edition=7th |access-date=2017-12-27 |archive-date=2016-03-07 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160307153610/http://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/101#Mill_0199_1342 |url-status=live }}</ref></blockquote> |
|||
{{libertarian socialism sidebar}} |
|||
=== Պատերազմ === |
|||
Քրիստիանիի նախագահության առաջին ամիսները նշանավորվել են քաղաքացիական պատերազմի կտրուկ սրմամբ։ 1989 թվականի նոյեմբերի 11-ին Ֆարաբունդո մարտի ազգային ազատագրման ճակատի զինված ուժերը սկսել են զանգվածային հարձակում: Առաջին անգամ պարտիզանները հարձակվել են [[Սան Սալվադոր]]ի արվարձանների վրա: Նրանք մի շարք [[սպանություն]]ներ են կատարել իշխանամետ դիրքորոշմամբ հայտնի սպաների, պաշտոնյաների և մասնավոր անձանց նկատմամբ։ Կառավարությունը պատասխանել է [[Ձախեր|ձախակողմյան]] ակտիվիստների նկատմամբ բռնաճնշումների խստացմամբ և պատերազմական գոտում խիստ պատժիչ արշավանքներով: Ավելի վաղ «մահվան էսկադրոնները» մի քանի խոշոր [[ահաբեկչություն]]ներ են իրականացրել մայրաքաղաքում։ |
|||
==== Mutualism ==== |
|||
1989 թվականի նոյեմբերի 16-ին Ատլանտլ գումարտակի մարտիկները [[Կենտրոնական Ամերիկա]]յի համալսարանի [[Կաթոլիկություն|կաթոլիկ]] կենտրոնում սպանել են ութ մարդու։ Մահացել են վեց [[ճիզվիտ]] [[քահանա]]ներ (հինգ [[Իսպանիա|իսպանացիներ]], այդ թվում՝ Իգնացիո Էլյակուրիան, և մեկ սալվադորցի), նրանց տնային տնտեսուհին և նրա դուստրը։ Պատճառն այն է եղել, որ դ'Օբյուսոնի զինյալների կողմից սպանված [[արքեպիսկոպոս]] Օսկար Ռոմերոյի ժամանակներից ի վեր Սալվադորի կաթոլիկ եկեղեցին, հատկապես ճիզվիտները, համարվել են ձախակողմյան ուժերի դաշնակիցներ: Համալսարանի կաթոլիկ կենտրոնը դիտվել է որպես Ֆարաբունդո մարտի ազգային ազատագրման ճակատի կիսալեգալ բազա։ Պարտիզանական հարձակման ֆոնին որոշում է կայացվել չեզոքացնել այդ վտանգը։ Ալֆրեդո Քրիստիանին, որպես պետության ղեկավար և գերագույն գլխավոր հրամանատար, համարվել է տվյալ ակցիայի պատասխանատուն<ref>{{Cite web |url=https://aps.com.sv/piden-enjuiciar-a-cristiani-por-masacre-de-padres-jesuitas/ |title=Piden enjuiciar a Cristiani por masacre de padres jesuitas |access-date=2018-05-24 |archive-date=2020-02-02 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200202093812/https://aps.com.sv/piden-enjuiciar-a-cristiani-por-masacre-de-padres-jesuitas/ |deadlink=yes }}</ref>: |
|||
[[Pierre-Joseph Proudhon]] developed a theoretical system called [[Mutualism (economic theory)|mutualism]] which attacks the legitimacy of existing [[property rights]], [[subsidies]], [[corporations]], [[banking]] and [[Renting|rent]]. Proudhon envisioned a decentralized market where people would enter the market with equal power, negating [[wage slavery]].<ref>{{cite web |url=http://mutualist.blogspot.com/2006/01/eugene-plawiuk-on-anarchist-socialism.html |title=Eugene Plawiuk on Anarchist Socialism |first=Kevin |last=Carson |date=19 January 2006 |work=Mutualist Blog: Free Market Anti-Capitalism |access-date=2 March 2016 |archive-date=27 March 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190327032638/http://mutualist.blogspot.com/2006/01/eugene-plawiuk-on-anarchist-socialism.html |url-status=live }}</ref> Proponents believe that cooperatives, credit unions and other forms of worker ownership would become viable without being subject to the [[Sovereign state|state]]. Market socialism has also been used to describe some [[individualist anarchist]] works which argue that free markets help workers and weaken capitalists.<ref>{{cite book |author-link=Murray Bookchin |first=Murray |last=Bookchin |title=The Ghost of Anarcho-Syndicalism |year=1992}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |author-link=Robert Graham (historian) |first=Robert |last=Graham |title=The General Idea of Proudhon's Revolution |url=http://dwardmac.pitzer.edu/ANARCHIST_ARCHIVES/proudhon/grahamproudhon.html |access-date=2021-08-03 |archive-date=2021-06-29 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210629140713/http://dwardmac.pitzer.edu/ANARCHIST_ARCHIVES/proudhon/grahamproudhon.html |url-status=live }}</ref> |
|||
==== Individualist anarchism in the United States ==== |
|||
=== Աշխարհ === |
|||
For American anarchist historian Eunice Minette Schuster, "[i]t is apparent [...] that [[Proudhon]]ian Anarchism was to be found in the United States at least as early as 1848 and that it was not conscious of its affinity to the Individualist Anarchism of [[Josiah Warren]] and [[Stephen Pearl Andrews]]. [...] [[William B. Greene]] presented this Proudhonian Mutualism in its purest and most systematic form".<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.againstallauthority.org/NativeAmericanAnarchism.html |title=Native American Anarchism: A Study of Left-Wing American Individualism |first=Eunice Minette |last=Schuster |work=againstallauthority.org |access-date=2 March 2016 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160214200513/http://www.againstallauthority.org/NativeAmericanAnarchism.html |archive-date=14 February 2016}}</ref> Josiah Warren is widely regarded as the first American [[anarchist]],<ref name=Slate>{{cite news |last=Palmer |first=Brian |date=29 December 2010 |url=http://www.slate.com/id/2279457/ |title=What do anarchists want from us? |work=[[Slate.com]] |access-date=8 October 2013 |archive-date=1 September 2011 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110901161604/http://www.slate.com/id/2279457/ |url-status=live }}</ref> and the four-page weekly paper he edited during 1833, ''The Peaceful Revolutionist'', was the first anarchist periodical published,<ref name="bailie20"/> an enterprise for which he built his own printing press, cast his own type, and made his own printing plates.<ref name="bailie20"/> |
|||
1990 թվականի գարնանից սկսվել են կառավարության ինտենսիվ բանակցությունները Ֆարաբունդո մարտի ազգային ազատագրման ճակատի հետ։ Դաժան մարտերը, [[ահաբեկչություն]]ները, հաշվեհարդարները նշանավորել են ռազմական փակուղի։ Երկու կողմերն էլ գիտակցել են համաձայնության անհրաժեշտությունը, որին հասնելու փորձեր արվել են նաև նախկինում։ Խաղաղության վերջնական համաձայնագիրը ստորագրվել է 1992 թվականի հունվարի 16-ին [[Չապուլտեպեկ ամրոց]]ում ([[Մեխիկո]]): |
|||
Warren was a follower of [[Robert Owen]] and joined Owen's community at [[New Harmony, Indiana]]. Josiah Warren termed the phrase "[[cost the limit of price]]", with "cost" here referring not to monetary price paid but the labor one exerted to produce an item.<ref>"A watch has a ''cost'' and a ''value''. The COST consists of the amount of labor bestowed on the mineral or natural wealth, in converting it into metals...". Warren, Josiah. ''Equitable Commerce''</ref> Therefore, "[h]e proposed a system to pay people with certificates indicating how many hours of work they did. They could exchange the notes at local time stores for goods that took the same amount of time to produce".<ref name=Slate/> He put his theories to the test by establishing an experimental "labor for labor store" called the [[Cincinnati Time Store]] where trade was facilitated by notes backed by a promise to perform labor. The store proved successful and operated for three years after which it was closed so that Warren could pursue establishing colonies based on [[Mutualism (economic theory)|mutualism]]. These included [[Utopia, Ohio|Utopia]] and [[past and present anarchist communities#Modern Times (1851 to late 1860s)|Modern Times]]. Warren said that [[Stephen Pearl Andrews]]' ''The Science of Society'', published in 1852, was the most lucid and complete exposition of Warren's own theories.<ref>{{cite journal |first=Charles A. |last=Madison |title=Anarchism in the United States |journal=[[Journal of the History of Ideas]] |volume=6 |number=1 |date=January 1945 |pages=53|doi=10.2307/2707055 |jstor=2707055}}</ref> |
|||
Պարտիզանական բանակը զորացրվել է, նրա կադրերի մի մասը ինտեգրվել է նոր ուժային կառույցների մեջ։ Պետական անվտանգության, հետախուզության և հակահետախուզության մարմինները լուծարվեցին և վերակազմավորվեցին հավասարության հիմունքներով: Առանձնահատուկ նշանակություն է ունեցել սոցիալ-տնտեսական մասը՝ խոշոր հողատարածքների բաժանումը գյուղացիների միջև, նախկին պարտիզանների հողով օժտումը, արհմիությունների, բիզնես ասոցիացիաների և կառավարության ներկայացուցչական մարմնի ստեղծումը պետական տնտեսական քաղաքականության ժողովրդավարական քննարկման համար<ref>[https://web.archive.org/web/20070306154227/http://www.elsalvador.com/noticias/especiales/acuerdosdepaz2002/index.html Acuerdos de Paz 1992—2002]</ref>: Քաղաքացիական պատերազմի ավարտը Ալֆրեդո Քրիստիանիի նախագահության գլխավոր ձեռքբերումն է եղել։ |
|||
Later, [[Benjamin Tucker]] fused the economics of Warren and Proudhon and published these ideas in ''[[Liberty (1881–1908)|Liberty]]'' calling them "Anarchistic-Socialism".<ref name="Benjamin Tucker p. 404">{{cite book |author-link=Benjamin Tucker |first=Benjamin |last=Tucker |title=Instead of a Book |pages=404}}</ref> Tucker said: "[T]he fact that one class of men are dependent for their living upon the sale of their labour, while another class of men are relieved of the necessity of labour by being legally privileged to sell something that is not labour. [...] And to such a state of things I am as much opposed as anyone. But the minute you remove privilege [...] every man will be a labourer exchanging with fellow-labourers. [...] What Anarchistic-Socialism aims to abolish is usury [...] it wants to deprive capital of its reward".<ref name="Benjamin Tucker p. 404"/> American [[individualist anarchists]] such as Tucker saw themselves as economic market socialists and political individualists while arguing that their "anarchistic socialism" or "individual anarchism" was "consistent [[Manchesterism]]".<ref>{{cite book |author-link=Benjamin Tucker |first=Benjamin |last=Tucker |title=Individual Liberty: Selections from the Writings of Benjamin R. Tucker |year=1926 |location=New York |publisher=[[Vanguard Press]] |pages=1–19}}</ref> [[Left-wing market anarchism]] is a modern branch of [[free-market anarchism]] that is based on a revival of such market socialist theories.<ref>{{cite book |editor1-first=Gary |editor1-last=Chartier |editor1-link=Gary Chartier |editor2-first=Charles W. |editor2-last=Johnson |editor2-link=Charles W. Johnson (jurist) |title=Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty |publisher=Minor Compositions |edition=1 |date=5 November 2011}}</ref><ref>{{cite conference |first1=Gary |last1=Chartier |author1-link=Gary Chartier |title=Advocates of Freed Markets Should Oppose Capitalism |conference=Free-Market Anti-Capitalism? |publisher=[[Association of Private Enterprise Education]] |location=Cæsar's Palace, Las Vegas, NV |date=13 April 2010}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |first1=Gary |last1=Chartier |author1-link=Gary Chartier |title=Advocates of Freed Markets Should Embrace 'Anti-Capitalism' |url=http://c4ss.org/content/1738 |access-date=2014-05-05 |archive-date=2019-09-29 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190929195335/http://c4ss.org/content/1738 |url-status=live }}</ref><ref>{{cite book |first1=Gary |last1=Chartier |author1-link=Gary Chartier |author2=Tulsa Alliance of the Libertarian Left |url=http://invisiblemolotov.wordpress.com/2009/09/12/socialist-ends-market-means/ |title=Socialist Ends, Market Means: Five Essays |date=12 September 2009 |publisher=Center for a Stateless Society |access-date=5 May 2014 |archive-date=28 March 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190328044107/https://c4ss.org/content/1738 |url-status=live }}</ref> |
|||
Չապուլտեպեկի համաձայնություններից մեկ ամիս անց մահացել է Ռոբերտո դ'Օբյուսոնը: Նախագահ Քրիստիանին, նախկինում ստիպված լինելով անընդհատ հետ նայել կուսակցության հիմնադրի դիրքորոշմանը, դարձել է ԱՀԴ-ի անվերապահ առաջնորդը<ref>{{Cite web |url=https://www.nytimes.com/1992/02/21/world/roberto-d-aubuisson-48-far-rightist-in-salvador.html |title=Roberto d’Aubuisson, 48, Far-Rightist in Salvador |access-date=2018-05-24 |archive-date=2018-05-21 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180521024844/https://www.nytimes.com/1992/02/21/world/roberto-d-aubuisson-48-far-rightist-in-salvador.html |deadlink=no }}</ref>: |
|||
=== Neoclassical economics === |
|||
=== Քաղաքականություն === |
|||
[[File:FreeMarketAntiCapitalist.jpg|thumb|upright=1.2|[[Libertarian socialist]] mural reading "Free market, [[anti-capitalism|anti-capitalist]]"]] |
|||
Ալֆրեդո Քրիստիանին [[չիլի]]ական [[Աուգուստո Պինոչետ|Պինոչետ]]ի մոդելի կողմնակիցն է եղել, հետաքրքրությամբ է վերաբերվել [[Հարավային Կորեա]]յում Պակ Չժոն Հիի և [[Թայվան]]ում [[Գոմինդան]]ի փորձին։ Նրա քաղաքականությունը բնութագրվել է լայնածավալ [[Նեոլիբերալիզմ|նեոլիբերալ]] բարեփոխումներով. բանկերի և խոշոր [[անշարժ գույք]]ի օբյեկտների սեփականաշնորհում, բյուջետային ծախսերի կրճատում, հարկերի և ներմուծման տուրքերի նվազեցում, գների վերահսկողության վերացում, բիզնեսի և առևտրի կանոնների պարզեցում, Կոլոնի փոխարժեքը դոլարի հետ կապելը։ Այս դասընթացին աջակցել է ձեռնարկատիրական համայնքը, որի վառ ներկայացուցիչը եղել է հիմնադիրներից մեկը՝ Արենա Ռիկարդո Վալդիվյեսոն։ Նման քաղաքականությունը նպաստել է ներդրումների աճին և օտարերկրյա վարկերի ստացմանը։ Այս գործոնների համադրությունը արտացոլվել է Սալվադորի ՀՆԱ-ի նկատելի աճի մեջ: |
|||
==== Early 20th century ==== |
|||
Beginning in the early 20th century, [[neoclassical economic theory]] provided the theoretical basis for more comprehensive models of market socialism. Early neoclassical models of socialism included a role for a central planning board (CPB) in setting prices equal to [[marginal cost]] in order to achieve [[Pareto efficiency]]. Although these early models did not rely on conventional markets, they were labeled market socialist for their utilization of financial prices and calculation. Alternative outlines for market socialism involve models where socially owned enterprises or producer co-operatives operate within [[free market]]s under the criterion of profitability. In recent models proposed by American neoclassical economists, public ownership of the means of production is achieved through public ownership of [[Equity (finance)|equity]] and social control of investment. |
|||
The earliest models of neoclassical socialism were developed by [[Léon Walras]], [[Enrico Barone]] (1908)<ref>{{cite book |first=F. |last=Caffé |date=1987 |chapter=Barone, Enrico |title=[[New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics|The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics]] |publisher=[[Palgrave Macmillan]] |isbn=978-1-56159-197-8 |volume= 1 |pages=195}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |first=Enrico |last=Barone |author-link=Enrico Barone |title=Il Ministro della Produzione nello Stato Collettivista |journal=Giornale degli Economisti |volume=2 |pages=267–93 |language=it |trans-title=The Ministry of Production in the Collectivist State}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |editor-first=Friedrich |editor-last=Hayek |editor-link=F. A. Hayek |date=1935 |title=Collectivist Economic Planning |isbn=978-0-7100-1506-8 |pages=245–290}}</ref> and [[Oskar R. Lange]] (c. 1936).<ref>{{cite book |first=Robin |last=Hahnel |date=2005 |title=Economic Justice and Democracy |publisher=[[Routledge]] |isbn=978-0-415-93344-5 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=m3QMGLrRbSAC&q=%22Economic+Justice+and+Democracy%22+Hahnel+%22usually+called+market+socialist+models%22&pg=PA170 |pages=170 |access-date=2021-08-10 |archive-date=2024-02-08 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208021200/https://books.google.com/books?id=m3QMGLrRbSAC&q=%22Economic+Justice+and+Democracy%22+Hahnel+%22usually+called+market+socialist+models%22&pg=PA170#v=snippet&q=%22Economic%20Justice%20and%20Democracy%22%20Hahnel%20%22usually%20called%20market%20socialist%20models%22&f=false |url-status=live }}</ref> Lange and [[Fred M. Taylor]] (1929)<ref>{{cite journal |last=Taylor |first=Fred M. |year=1929 |title=The Guidance of Production in a Socialist State |journal=The American Economic Review |volume=19 |issue=1 |pages=1–8 |jstor=1809581}}</ref> proposed that central planning boards set prices through "trial and error", making adjustments as shortages and surpluses occurred rather than relying on a [[free price mechanism]]. If there were shortages, prices would be raised; if there were surpluses, prices would be lowered.<ref>{{cite book |first=Mark |last=Skousen |date=2001 |title=Making Modern Economics |publisher=M.E. Sharpe |isbn=978-0-7656-0479-8 |url=https://archive.org/details/makingofmodernec0000skou/page/414 |pages=414–415}} <!-- quote=Skousen "Making of Modern Economics" "channeled through a central planning board". --></ref> Raising the prices would encourage businesses to increase production, driven by their desire to increase their profits, and in doing so eliminate the shortage. Lowering the prices would encourage businesses to curtail production to prevent losses, which would eliminate the surplus. Therefore, it would be a simulation of the market mechanism, which Lange thought would be capable of effectively managing supply and demand.<ref>{{cite book |first=János |last=Kornai |author-link=János Kornai |date=1992 |title=The Socialist System: the political economy of communism |publisher=[[Oxford University Press]] |isbn=978-0-19-828776-6 |pages=476}}</ref> |
|||
Հակառակ կողմը սոցիալական խնդիրների սրումն է եղել, գործազրկության և հանցավորության աճը։ Քրիստիանիի, նրա ընտանիքի անդամների և Մերձավոր կուսակցական համախոհների նկատմամբ կասկածներ են առաջացել կոռուպցիայի վերաբերյալ<ref name=acb2>{{Cite web |url=https://lavanguardiaelsalvador.wordpress.com/2010/02/05/las-presidencias-de-el-salvador-ii-alfredo-felix-cristiani/ |title=Las presidencias dela República de El Salvador II: Alfredo Felix Cristiani B |access-date=2018-05-24 |archive-date=2018-05-24 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180524222855/https://lavanguardiaelsalvador.wordpress.com/2010/02/05/las-presidencias-de-el-salvador-ii-alfredo-felix-cristiani/ |deadlink=no }}</ref>: Դրան նպաստել է Քրիստիանիի ընտանեկան բիզնեսը՝ «SCB» ագրոընկերությունը «Monsanto Company»-ին վաճառվել է միայն 2008 թվականի ամռանը<ref>{{Cite web |url=https://monsanto.com/news-releases/monsanto-company-announces-agreement-to-acquire-semillas-cristiani-burkard-the-leading-central-american-corn-seed-company/ |title=Monsanto Company Announces Agreement to Acquire Semillas Cristiani Burkard, the Leading Central American Corn Seed Company |access-date=2018-05-24 |archive-date=2018-05-25 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180525063945/https://monsanto.com/news-releases/monsanto-company-announces-agreement-to-acquire-semillas-cristiani-burkard-the-leading-central-american-corn-seed-company/ |deadlink=yes }}</ref>: |
|||
Although the [[Lange model|Lange–Lerner model]] was often labelled as market socialism, it is better described as market simulation because factor markets did not exist for the allocation of capital goods. The objective of the Lange–Lerner model was explicitly to replace markets with a non-market system of resource allocation.<ref>{{cite book |last=Steele |first=David Ramsay |author-link=David Ramsey Steele |title=From Marx to Mises: Post Capitalist Society and the Challenge of Economic Calculation |publisher=Open Court |date=September 1999 |isbn=978-0875484495 |page=151 |quote=Finally, there is the curious circumstance that Lange's system is widely hailed as a pioneering effort in the theory of market socialism, when it is demonstrably no such thing: even the name 'market socialism' predates Lange, and Lange's system is explicitly a proposal to replace the market with a non-market system.}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Aslund |first=Anders |title=Market Socialism Or the Restoration of Capitalism? |publisher=[[Cambridge University Press]] |date=1992 |isbn=9780521411936 |page=20 |quote=Usually Oskar Lange is regarded as the originator of the concept of market socialism, in spite of the fact that he never spoke of market socialism and would not have been the first if he had. In fact, Lange's model involves only a partial market simulation for the trial-and-error iterative construction of a central plan, which belongs to the set of decentralization procedures in central planning.}}</ref> |
|||
Ներքին քաղաքականության, սոցիալական և մշակութային կյանքում Քրիստիանիի կառավարությունը պահպանողական դասընթաց է անցկացրել՝ կենտրոնանալով [[Կաթոլիկություն|կաթոլիկ]] արժեքների և դ'Օբյուսոնի «Սալվադոր առաջին, երկրորդ, երրորդ» [[Ազգայնականություն|ազգայնական]] սկզբունքի վրա: Ընդ որում, ԱՀԴ-ն փորձել է փոխել «մահվան էսկադրոնների» կուսակցության ներկայիս իմիջը և հանդես գալ որպես «ժամանակակից պահպանողական կուսակցություն»։ Այնուամենայնիվ, ԱՀԴ-ի ներկայացուցիչները անընդհատ շեշտել են հավատարմությունը «դ'Օբյուսոնի ուխտերին»: Քրիստիանին պնդել է, որ միայն դ'Օբյուսոնի մասնակցության շնորհիվ է Սալվադորին հաջողվել հասնել խաղաղության<ref>{{Cite web |url=https://www.washingtonpost.com/archive/politics/1994/03/17/a-ghost-in-salvadors-elections/e69818a7-6e43-4252-b9b4-0786049eaaf4/ |title=A GHOST IN SALVADOR’S ELECTIONS |access-date=2018-05-24 |archive-date=2018-07-08 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180708021526/https://www.washingtonpost.com/archive/politics/1994/03/17/a-ghost-in-salvadors-elections/e69818a7-6e43-4252-b9b4-0786049eaaf4/ |deadlink=no }}</ref>: |
|||
H. D. Dickinson published two articles proposing a form of market socialism, namely "Price Formation in a Socialist Community" (''[[The Economic Journal]]'' 1933) and "The Problems of a Socialist Economy" (''The Economic Journal'' 1934). Dickinson proposed a mathematical solution whereby the problems of a socialist economy could be solved by a central planning agency. The central agency would have the necessary statistics on the economy, as well as the capability of using statistics to direct production. The economy could be represented as a system of equations. Solution values for these equations could be used to price all goods at marginal cost and direct production. Hayek (1935) argued against the proposal to simulate markets with equations. Dickinson (1939) adopted the Lange-Taylor proposal to simulate markets through trial and error. |
|||
== Ընտանիք == |
|||
Ալֆրեդո Քրիստիանին ամուսնացած է եղել գործարար Մարգարիտա Լյակի հետ, ունեցել երկու որդի և մեկ դուստր: Մարգարիտա Լյակը դե Քրիստիանին հայտնի է եղել որպես [[Նկարչություն|նկարչուհի]] և նկարչական ցուցահանդեսների կազմակերպիչ<ref>{{Cite web |url=http://archivo.elsalvador.com/mwedh/nota/nota_completa.asp?idCat=47868&idArt=7289916 |title=Margarita de Cristiani: «Me siento muy orgullosa por esta exposición» |accessdate=2018-05-24 |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20180524222022/http://archivo.elsalvador.com/mwedh/nota/nota_completa.asp?idCat=47868&idArt=7289916 |archivedate=2018-05-24 |deadlink=yes }}</ref>: Ձախակողմյան աղբյուրները պնդել են, որ 1970-1980-ական թվականների սկզբին Լյակ ընտանիքի պահպանությունն ու անվտանգությունն ապահովել է «մահվան էսկադրոնի» հրամանատար Հեկտոր Անտոնիո Ռեգալադոն<ref>{{Cite web |url=https://resistenciamusical.wordpress.com/2012/04/13/los-escuadrones-de-la-muerte-tercer-periodo-responsabilidad-compartida-entre-militares-y-civiles-1980-1989/ |title=Los Escuadrones de la Muerte: TERCER PERIODO: Responsabilidad compartida entre militares y civiles (1980-1989) |access-date=2018-06-30 |archive-date=2018-08-26 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180826123026/https://resistenciamusical.wordpress.com/2012/04/13/los-escuadrones-de-la-muerte-tercer-periodo-responsabilidad-compartida-entre-militares-y-civiles-1980-1989/ |deadlink=no }}</ref>: |
|||
The Lange–Dickinson version of market socialism kept capital investment out of the market. Lange (1926 p65) insisted that a central planning board would have to set [[capital accumulation]] rates arbitrarily. Lange and Dickinson saw potential problems with bureaucratization in market socialism. According to Dickinson, "the attempt to check irresponsibility will tie up managers of socialist enterprises with so much red tape and bureaucratic regulation that they will lose all initiative and independence" (Dickinson 1938, p. 214). In ''The Economics of Control: Principles of Welfare Economics'' (1944), Abba Lerner admitted that capital investment would be politicized in market socialism. |
|||
Գործարար կին և քաղաքական ակտիվիստ Կլաուդիա Քրիստիանին կողմ է եղել աբորտների ապաքրեականացմանը՝ չնայած իր հոր կուսակցության պաշտոնական դիրքորոշմանը<ref>{{Cite web |url=https://elfaro.net/es/201804/el_salvador/21770/%E2%80%9CSimple-y-sencillamente-no-est%C3%A1n-los-votos-para-despenalizar-el-aborto%E2%80%9D.htm |title=«Simple y sencillamente no están los votos para despenalizar el aborto» |access-date=2018-05-24 |archive-date=2018-05-24 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180524222405/https://elfaro.net/es/201804/el_salvador/21770/%E2%80%9CSimple-y-sencillamente-no-est%C3%A1n-los-votos-para-despenalizar-el-aborto%E2%80%9D.htm |deadlink=no }}</ref>: |
|||
==== Late 20th century and early 21st century ==== |
|||
== Ծանոթագրություններ == |
|||
[[File:Richard Wolff explaining capitalist planning.jpg|thumb|[[Richard D. Wolff]] is a Marxian economist who is a proponent of workers self-directed enterprises.]] |
|||
{{ծանցանկ|2}} |
|||
Economists active in the former Yugoslavia, including Czech-born [[Jaroslav Vaněk]] and Croat-born [[Branko Horvat]], promoted a model of market socialism dubbed the Illyrian model, where firms were socially owned by their employees and structured around [[workers' self-management]], competing with each other in open and free markets. |
|||
American economists in the latter half of the 20th century developed models based such as coupon socialism (by the economist [[John Roemer]]) and [[Economic democracy#The market|economic democracy]] (by the philosopher [[David Schweickart]]). |
|||
[[Pranab Bardhan]] and [[John Roemer]] proposed a form of market socialism where there was a stock market that distributed shares of the capital stock equally among citizens. In this stock market, there is no buying or selling of stocks that leads to negative externalities associated with a concentration of capital ownership. The Bardhan and Roemer model satisfied the main requirements of both socialism (workers own all the factors of production, not just labour) and market economies (prices determine efficient allocation of resources). New Zealand economist Steven O'Donnell expanded on the Bardhan and Roemer model and decomposed the capital function in a general equilibrium system to take account of entrepreneurial activity in market socialist economies. O'Donnell (2003) set up a model that could be used as a blueprint for transition economies and the results suggested that although market socialist models were inherently unstable in the long term, they would provide in the short term the economic infrastructure necessary for a successful transition from planned to market economies. |
|||
In the early 21st century, the [[Marxian economist]] [[Richard D. Wolff]] refocused Marxian economics giving it a microfoundational focus. The core idea was that transition from capitalism to socialism required the reorganization of the enterprise from a top-down hierarchical capitalist model to a model where all key enterprise decisions (what, how, and where to produce and what to do with outputs) were made on a one-worker, one vote basis. Wolff called them workers self-directed enterprises (WSDEs). How they would interact with one another and with consumers was left open to democratic social decisions and could entail markets or planning, or likely mixtures of both. |
|||
Advocates of market socialism such as [[Jaroslav Vaněk]] argue that genuinely free markets are not possible under conditions of private ownership of productive property. Instead, he contends that the class differences and inequalities in income and power that result from private ownership enable the interests of the dominant class to skew the market to their favor, either in the form of monopoly and market power, or by utilizing their wealth and resources to legislate government policies that benefit their specific business interests. Additionally, Vaněk states that workers in a socialist economy based on cooperative and self-managed enterprises have stronger incentives to maximize productivity because they would receive a share of the profits (based on the overall performance of their enterprise) in addition to receiving their fixed wage or salary. The stronger incentives to maximize productivity that he conceives as possible in a socialist economy based on cooperative and self-managed enterprises might be accomplished in a free-market economy if [[employee-owned companies]] were the norm as envisioned by various thinkers including [[Louis O. Kelso]] and [[James S. Albus]].<ref>{{cite magazine |magazine=New Renaissance Magazine |url=http://www.ru.org/index.php/30-economics/357-cooperative-economics-an-interview-with-jaroslav-vanek |title=Cooperative Economics: An Interview with Jaroslav Vanek |first=Albert |last=Perkins |access-date=17 March 2011 |volume=5 |number=1 |archive-date=17 August 2021 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210817073532/http://www.ru.org/index.php/30-economics/357-cooperative-economics-an-interview-with-jaroslav-vanek |url-status=live }}</ref> |
|||
Giacomo Corneo, Professor of Public Finance and Social Policy at the Free University of Berlin, espouses an "updated version of market socialism" where large firms would be publicly owned (though by no more than 51% share),<ref>{{cite book |last=Corneo |first=Giacomo |title=s Capitalism Obsolete? A Journey through Alternative Economic Systems |publisher=[[Harvard University Press]] |year=2017 |location=Cambridge, MA |quote=...the federal shareholder should retain only 51 percent of their shares. Private ownership of the remaining 29% percent has a key role to play in creating an incentive structure that leads those firms to maximize profits.}}</ref> which would allow the government to distribute a social dividend, while the rest of the firms would be privately owned and subject to regulations to protect employees, consumers and environment.<ref>{{cite web |date=8 December 2018 |title=Towards Shareholder Socialism? {{!}} An interview with Giacomo Corneo |url=https://medium.com/@circularconversations/towards-shareholder-socialism-an-interview-with-giacomo-corneo-22473aad4377 |website=[[Medium (website)|Medium]] |quote=The blueprint has private ownership in the means of production with respect to small- and medium-sized firms, because we think that individualism at the level of entrepreneurial initiatives is an important ingredient for economic dynamism. But all large firms would be in public ownership, and this would be the key difference with respect to today's economic system. |access-date=28 January 2022 |archive-date=28 January 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220128212209/https://medium.com/@circularconversations/towards-shareholder-socialism-an-interview-with-giacomo-corneo-22473aad4377 |url-status=live }}</ref> |
|||
[[Matt Bruenig]] advocates for a version of market socialism he calls "funds socialism," which involves [[sovereign wealth fund]]s acquiring shares of private enterprises to socialize ownership and control of firms.<ref name=":2">{{Cite web |last=Bruenig |first=Matt |date=28 September 2018 |title=Common Wealth: workers' ownership in the history of socialism |url=https://www.versobooks.com/blogs/news/4054-common-wealth-workers-ownership-in-the-history-of-socialism |access-date=2023-08-11 |website=Verso |language=en |archive-date=2023-08-11 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230811004526/https://www.versobooks.com/blogs/news/4054-common-wealth-workers-ownership-in-the-history-of-socialism |url-status=live }}</ref><ref name=":1">{{cite web |last=Bruenig |first=Matt |date=February 11, 2017 |title=Nickel-and-Dime Socialism |url=https://medium.com/@MattBruenig/nickel-and-dime-socialism-47fcec406295 |access-date=October 14, 2018 |website=Medium |archive-date=October 14, 2018 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20181014091527/https://medium.com/@MattBruenig/nickel-and-dime-socialism-47fcec406295 |url-status=live }}</ref> Bruenig claims that this form of market socialism is similar to that advocated by [[Yanis Varoufakis]], [[Rudolf Meidner]], and [[John Roemer]].<ref name=":1" /> |
|||
=== Anti-equilibrium economics === |
|||
Another form of market socialism has been promoted by critics of [[central planning]] and generally of neoclassical [[general equilibrium theory]]. The most notable of these economists were [[Alec Nove]] and [[János Kornai]]. In particular, in 1983 Nove proposed what he called "feasible socialism",<ref>Nove, A. (1983), ''The Economics of Feasible Socialism'', Unwin Hyman</ref> a mixed economy consisting of state-run enterprises, autonomous publicly owned firms, cooperatives and small-scale private enterprise operating in a market economy that included a role for macroeconomic planning.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.whatnextjournal.co.uk/Pages/Ratner/Feassoc.html |title=Feasible Socialism: Market or Plan – Or Both |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20081120135611/http://www.whatnextjournal.co.uk/Pages/Ratner/Feassoc.html |archive-date=20 November 2008|access-date=14 November 2023}}</ref> |
|||
== In practice == |
|||
A number of market socialist elements have existed in various economies. The [[Economy of the Socialist Federal Republic of Yugoslavia|economy]] of [[Socialist Federal Republic of Yugoslavia|Yugoslavia]] was widely considered to have been a form of market-based socialism, based on [[Social ownership|socially-owned cooperatives]], [[workers' self-management]], and [[Market (economics)|market allocation of capital]].<ref name="V.P. Gagnon, Jr.">{{cite journal |last1=Gagnon |first1=V.P. Jr. |author1-link= |date=Summer 1991 |title=Yugoslavia: Prospects for Stability |url=https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/europe/1991-06-01/yugoslavia-prospects-stability |journal=[[Foreign Affairs]] |volume=70 |issue=3 |pages=17–35 |doi=10.2307/20044816 |jstor=20044816 |access-date=24 August 2021 |archive-date=2021-08-24 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210824110922/https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/europe/1991-06-01/yugoslavia-prospects-stability |url-status=live }}</ref> Some of the economic reforms introduced during the [[Prague Spring]] by [[Alexander Dubček]], the [[Communist Party of Czechoslovakia#Leaders|leader]] of [[Czechoslovakia]], included elements of market socialism.<ref>{{cite book |first=Galia |last=Golan |date=1971 |title=Reform Rule in Czechoslovakia: The Dubcek Era 1968–1969 |publisher=[[Cambridge University Press]] |isbn=9780521085861}}</ref> |
|||
Likewise, [[Vietnam]]'s [[socialist-oriented market economy]] is self-described as market socialist. It has an extremely high prevalence of cooperatives, especially in agriculture and retail, with the continued [[state ownership]] of the [[commanding heights of the economy]].<ref>{{cite journal |url=http://tapchiqptd.vn/en/events-and-comments/key-role-of-the-state-economic-sector-in-vietnams-socialistoriented-market-economy-undeniable/14196.html |title=Key role of the state economic sector in Vietnam's socialist-oriented market economy undeniable |author=Luong Minh Cu |journal=National Defence Journal |date=13 August 2019 |access-date=5 August 2020 }}{{Dead link|date=September 2023 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}</ref> Cooperative businesses in Vietnam are also incentivized and supported by the government, receiving many benefits that private companies do not.<ref>{{cite news |url=https://www.vietnambreakingnews.com/2020/03/vietnam-to-release-white-book-on-cooperatives/ |title=Vietnam to release white book on cooperatives |work=VietNam Breaking News |date=10 March 2020 |access-date=5 August 2020 |archive-date=8 July 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200708092809/https://www.vietnambreakingnews.com/2020/03/vietnam-to-release-white-book-on-cooperatives/ |url-status=live }}</ref> |
|||
[[Peter Drucker]] described the United States system of regulated pension funds providing capital to financial markets as "pension fund socialism".<ref>{{cite book |last=Drucker |first=Peter Ferdinand |date=1976 |title=The Unseen Revolution: How Pension Fund Socialism Came to America |publisher=[[HarperCollins]] |isbn=9780060110970}}</ref> [[William H. Simon]] characterized pension fund socialism as "a form of market socialism", concluding that it was promising but perhaps with prospects more limited than those envisioned by its enthusiasts.<ref>{{cite book |last=Simon |first=William H. |date=1995 |chapter=Prospects for Pension Fund Socialism |editor1-last=McCahery |editor1-first=J. |editor2-last=Picciotto |editor2-first=Sol |editor3-last=Scott |editor3-first=Colin |title=Corporate Control and Accountability: Changing Structures and the Dynamics |publisher=[[Oxford University Press]] |pages=167 |isbn=9780198259909}}</ref> |
|||
The [[Economy of Cuba|economy]] of [[Cuba]] under the rule of [[Raúl Castro]] has been described as attempting market socialist reforms.<ref>{{cite web |url=https://www.bbc.com/news/business-12565417 |title=Cuba inches towards market socialism |work=[[BBC News]] |date=27 March 2011 |access-date=30 December 2019 |archive-date=29 September 2023 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230929020629/https://www.bbc.com/news/business-12565417 |url-status=live }}</ref> Similarly, the economy of [[History of Libya under Muammar Gaddafi|Libya under Muammar Gaddafi]] could be described as a form of market socialism as [[Muammar Gaddafi]]'s [[Third International Theory]] shared many similarities with [[Socialist self-management|Yugoslav self-management]].<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.rcmlibya.org/English/RCM%20(1).pdf |title=Lybia |url-status=dead |website=Revolutionary Committees Movement |access-date=2020-07-08 |archive-date=2023-04-26 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230426153335/http://www.rcmlibya.org/English/RCM%20(1).pdf }}</ref><ref>{{cite news |last=Iveković |first=Ivan |date=3 April 2009 |url=http://www.h-alter.org/vijesti/libijska-dzamahirija-zmedju-proslosti-i-sadasnjosti-1-dio |title=Libijska džamahirija između prošlosti i sadašnjosti - 1. dio |trans-title=Libyan Jamahiriya between past and present - Part 1 |work=H-Alter |language=hr |access-date=5 August 2020 |archive-date=1 February 2014 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140201224319/http://www.h-alter.org/vijesti/svijet/libijska-dzamahirija-zmedju-proslosti-i-sadasnjosti-1-dio }}</ref> |
|||
Policies similar to the market socialist proposal of a [[social dividend]] and [[Basic income guarantee|basic income]] scheme have been implemented on the basis of public ownership of natural resources in Alaska ([[Alaska Permanent Fund]]) and in Norway (the [[Government Pension Fund of Norway]]).<ref name=":2" /> |
|||
After a decade of political, social and economic turmoil following the [[Cultural Revolution]], [[People's Republic of China|China]] began its [[reform and opening-up]] in 1978 and formally amended its constitution in adopting the [[socialist market economy]] as the country's economic system in 1993.<ref>{{Cite web |title=China: Is its 'socialist market economy' era over? – DW – 03/29/2023 |url=https://www.dw.com/en/china-is-its-socialist-market-economy-era-over/a-65140920 |access-date=2024-07-01 |website=dw.com |language=en}}</ref> |
|||
== Relation to political ideologies == |
|||
=== Marxism–Leninism === |
|||
{{Main articles|Marxism–Leninism}} |
|||
The phrase market socialism has occasionally been used in reference to any attempt by a [[Soviet-type economic planning|Soviet-type planned economy]] to introduce market elements into its economic system. In this sense, market socialism was first attempted during the 1920s in the Soviet Union as the [[New Economic Policy]] (NEP) before being abandoned. Later, elements of market socialism were introduced in Hungary (nicknamed [[goulash communism]]), Czechoslovakia (sloganized as [[socialism with a human face]]), Yugoslavia (known as [[Titoism]]) in the 1970s and 1980s. The contemporary [[Economy of Belarus]] has been described as a market socialist system. The [[Soviet Union]] attempted to introduce a market system with its [[perestroika]] reforms under [[Mikhail Gorbachev]]. During the later stages there was talk within top circles that the Soviet Union should move toward a market-based socialist system. |
|||
Historically, these kinds of market socialist systems attempt to retain state ownership of the [[commanding heights of the economy]] such as heavy industry, energy and infrastructure while introducing decentralised decision making and giving local managers more freedom to make decisions and respond to market demands. Market socialist systems also allow private ownership and [[entrepreneur]]ship in the service and other secondary economic sectors. The [[Market (economics)|market]] is allowed to determine prices for consumer goods and agricultural products, and farmers are allowed to sell all or some of their products on the open market and keep some or all of the profit as an incentive to increase and improve production. |
|||
Both the Eastern European and Chinese socialist approaches to market reforms assume that a "market economy" is not necessarily a capitalist market economy, and that a socialist economy is not necessarily a planned economy.<ref name=":0">{{Cite journal |last=Boer |first=Roland |author-link=Roland Boer |date=2021-10-01 |title=From Belgrade to Beijing : Comparing Socialist Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe and China |journal=World Review of Political Economy |volume=12 |pages=299 |doi=10.13169/worlrevipoliecon.12.3.0296 |s2cid=247967541 |issn=2042-8928|doi-access=free }}</ref> This view draws support from Karl Marx's observations that markets existed under historical modes of production such as the Roman slave market economy and feudal markets.<ref name=":0" /> |
|||
=== Socialism with Chinese characteristics === |
|||
{{main|Socialism with Chinese characteristics|Socialist market economy}} |
|||
The term market socialism has been used to refer to reformed economic systems in [[Marxist–Leninist state]]s, most notably in reference to the contemporary economy of the [[People's Republic of China]], where a [[free price system]] is used for the allocation of capital goods in both the state and private sectors. However, Chinese political and economic proponents of the [[socialist market economy]] do not consider it to be a form of market socialism in the neoclassical sense<ref name=Duan>{{cite web |url=http://www.nodo50.org/cubasigloXXI/congreso06/conf3_zhonquiao.pdf |title=Market Economy and Socialist Road |first=Duan |last=Zhongqiao |access-date=4 February 2016 |archive-date=10 July 2012 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120710134716/http://www.nodo50.org/cubasigloXXI/congreso06/conf3_zhonquiao.pdf |url-status=live }}</ref> and many Western economists and political scientists question the degree to which this model constitutes a form of market socialism, often preferring to describe it as [[state capitalism]].<ref name="Market socialism or Capitalism? Evidence from Chinese Financial Market Development">{{cite journal |title=Market socialism or Capitalism? Evidence from Chinese Financial Market Development, 2005 |last1=Du |first1=Julan |last2=Xu |first2=Chenggang |date=April 2005 |journal=International Economic Association 2005 Round Table on Market and Socialism}}</ref> |
|||
Although similar in name, market socialism differs markedly from the socialist market economy and [[socialist-oriented market economy]] models practiced in the contemporary [[People's Republic of China]] and [[Socialist Republic of Vietnam]], respectively. Officially these economic systems represent market economies that are in the long-term process of transition toward socialism.<ref name="links.org.au">{{cite web |url=http://links.org.au/node/14 |title=Socialism and the market: China and Vietnam compared |first=Michael |last=Karadjis |publisher=Links International Journal for Socialist Renewal |access-date=20 March 2013 |archive-date=10 April 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190410125949/http://links.org.au/node/14 |url-status=live }}</ref> Key differences between models of market socialism and the Chinese and Vietnamese models include the role of private investment in enterprises, the lack of a social dividend or basic income system to equitably distribute state profits among the population and the existence and role of financial markets in the Chinese model—markets which are absent in the market socialist literature.<ref name="Market socialism or Capitalism? Evidence from Chinese Financial Market Development"/> |
|||
The Chinese experience with [[socialism with Chinese characteristics]] is frequently referred to as a socialist market economy where the [[Commanding heights of the economy|commanding heights]] are state-owned, but a substantial portion of both the state and private sectors of economy are governed by market practices, including a stock exchange for trading equity and the utilization of indirect macroeconomic market mechanisms (i.e. [[fiscal policy|fiscal]], [[Monetary policy|monetary]] and [[industrial policies]]) to influence the economy in the same manner governments affect the economy in capitalist economies. The market is the arbitrator for most economic activity, with economic planning being relegated to macro-economic government indicative planning that does not encompass the microeconomic decision-making that is left to the individual organizations and state-owned enterprises. This model includes a significant amount of privately owned firms that operate as a business for profit, but only for consumer goods and services.<ref name="adb.org">{{cite conference |url=http://www.adb.org/Documents/Events/2004/PRC_Planning_System_Reform/chow1.pdf |title=The Role of Planning in China's Market Economy |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20040526022816/http://www.adb.org/Documents/Events/2004/PRC_Planning_System_Reform/chow1.pdf |archive-date=26 May 2004 |first=Gregory C. |last=Chow |conference=International Conference on China's Planning System Reform |date=24–25 March 2004 |location=Beijing |website=Asian Development Bank}}</ref> |
|||
In the Chinese system, directive planning based on mandatory output requirements and quotas were displaced by market mechanisms for most of the economy, including both the state and private sectors, although the government engages in [[indicative planning]] for large state enterprises.<ref name="adb.org"/> In comparison with the Soviet-type planned economy, the Chinese socialist market model is based on the [[corporatization]] of state institutions, transforming them into joint-stock companies. As of 2008, there were 150 state-owned corporations directly under the central government.<ref>{{cite news |url=https://www.forbes.com/2008/07/08/china-enterprises-state-lead-cx_jrw_0708mckinsey.html |work=[[Forbes]] |title=Reassessing China's State-Owned Enterprises |date=8 July 2008 |access-date=4 September 2017 |archive-date=11 April 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190411122407/https://www.forbes.com/2008/07/08/china-enterprises-state-lead-cx_jrw_0708mckinsey.html |url-status=live }}</ref> These state-owned corporations have been reformed and become increasingly dynamic and a major source of revenue for the state in 2008,<ref>{{cite web |url=http://us.ft.com/ftgateway/superpage.ft?news_id%3Dfto031620081407384075 |title=InfoViewer: China's champions: Why state ownership is no longer proving a dead hand |access-date=2 June 2010 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110711045431/https://us.ft.com/ftgateway/superpage.ft?news_id=fto031620081407384075 |archive-date=11 July 2011}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |first1=David A. |last1=Ralston |first2=Jane |last2=Terpstra-Tong |first3=Robert H. |last3=Terpstra |first4=Xueli |last4=Wang |url=http://ufirc.ou.edu/publications/Enterprises%20of%20China.pdf |title=Today's State-Owned Enterprises of China: Are They Dying Dinosaurs or Dynamic Dynamos? |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110720024533/http://ufirc.ou.edu/publications/Enterprises%20of%20China.pdf |archive-date=20 July 2011}}</ref> leading the economic recovery in 2009 during the wake of the global financial crises.<ref>{{cite news |url=http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/business/8153138.stm |work=[[BBC News]] |title=China grows faster amid worries |date=16 July 2009 |access-date=12 May 2010 |archive-date=7 September 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190907074416/http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/business/8153138.stm |url-status=live }}</ref> |
|||
This economic model is defended from a [[Marxist–Leninist]] perspective which states that a planned socialist economy can only emerge after first developing the basis for socialism through the establishment of a market economy and commodity-exchange economy; and that socialism would only emerge after this stage has exhausted its historical necessity and gradually transforms itself into socialism.<ref name=Duan/> Proponents of this model argue that the economic system of the former Soviet Union and its [[Eastern Bloc|satellite states]] attempted to go from a natural economy to a planned economy by decree, without passing through the necessary market economy phase of development.<ref name=vn>{{cite book |last=Vuong |first=Quan-Hoang |date=February 2010 |title=Financial Markets in Vietnam's Transition Economy: Facts, Insights, Implications |location=Saarbrücken, Germany |publisher=[[VDM Publishing]] |isbn=978-3-639-23383-4}}</ref> |
|||
=== Democratic socialism === |
|||
{{Main articles|Democratic socialism}} |
|||
Some democratic socialists advocate forms of market socialism, some of which are based on self-management. Others advocate for a non-market [[Participatory economics|participatory economy]] based on decentralized economic planning.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Anderson |last2=Herr |first1=Gary L. |first2=Kathryn G. |title=Encyclopedia of Activism and Social Justice |publisher=[[SAGE Publications]], inc |year=2007 |isbn=978-1412918121 |page=448 |quote=Some have endorsed the concept of market socialism, a postcapitalist economy that retains market competition but socializes the means of production, and in some versions, extends democracy to the workplace. Some holdout for a nonmarket, participatory economy. All democratic socialists agree on the need for a democratic alternative to capitalism.}}</ref> |
|||
=== Anarchism === |
|||
{{main|Free-market anarchism|Individualist anarchism|Mutualism (economic theory)}} |
|||
[[File:Portrait of Pierre Joseph Proudhon 1865.jpg|thumb|[[Pierre-Joseph Proudhon]] was the primary proponent of [[Mutualism (economic theory)|mutualism]] and influenced many later [[individualist anarchist]] and [[social anarchist]] thinkers.]] |
|||
The French philosopher [[Pierre-Joseph Proudhon]] is the first person to call himself an [[wikt:anarchist|anarchist]] and considered among its most influential theorists. Proudhon is considered by many to be the "father of anarchism".<ref>{{cite book |first=Daniel |last=Guérin |author-link=Daniel Guérin |title=Anarchism: From Theory to Practice |location=New York |publisher=Monthly Review Press |date=1970}}</ref> Proudhon became a member of the [[French Parliament]] after the [[French Revolution of 1848]], whereon he referred to himself as a ''[[federalist]]''.<ref>{{cite book |last=Binkley |first=Robert C. |author-link=Robert C. Binkley |title=Realism and Nationalism 1852-1871 |publisher=Read Books |pages=118}}</ref> Proudhon's best-known assertion is that "[[Property is theft!]]", contained in his first major work ''What Is Property?'', published in 1840. The book's publication attracted the attention of the French authorities. It also attracted the scrutiny of [[Karl Marx]], who started a correspondence with Proudhon. The two influenced each other and met in Paris while Marx was exiled there. Their friendship finally ended when Marx responded to Proudhon's ''[[The Philosophy of Poverty]]'' with the provocatively titled ''[[The Poverty of Philosophy]]''. The dispute became one of the sources of the split between the anarchist and [[Marxist]] wings of the [[International Working Men's Association]]. [[Mutualism (economic theory)|Mutualism]] is an [[anarchist school of thought]] and market socialist [[economic theory]] that advocates a [[socialist]] society where each person possess a [[means of production]], either individually or collectively, with trade representing equivalent amounts of labor in the [[free market]].<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.mutualist.org/ |title=Introduction |publisher=Mutualist.org |access-date=29 April 2010 |archive-date=17 June 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190617182643/http://www.mutualist.org/ |url-status=live }}</ref> Integral to the scheme was the establishment of a mutual-credit bank that would lend to producers at a minimal interest rate, just high enough to cover administration.<ref>{{cite book |last=Miller |first=David |author-link=David Miller (political theorist) |date=1987 |chapter=Mutualism |title=The Blackwell Encyclopedia of Political Thought |publisher=[[Blackwell Publishing]] |pages=11}}</ref> Mutualism is based on a [[labor theory of value]] which holds that when labor or its product is sold it ought to receive in exchange goods or services embodying "the amount of labor necessary to produce an article of exactly similar and equal utility".<ref>{{cite book |last=Tandy |first=Francis D. |date=1896 |title=[[Voluntary Socialism]] |chapter=Chapter 6}}</ref> |
|||
Mutualism originated from the writings of Proudhon. Mutualists oppose the idea of individuals receiving an income through loans, investments and rent as they believe these individuals are not laboring. Although opposed this type of income, Proudhon expressed that he had never intended "to forbid or suppress, by sovereign decree, ground rent and interest on capital. I think that all these manifestations of human activity should remain free and voluntary for all: I ask for them no modifications, restrictions or suppressions, other than those which result naturally and of necessity from the universalization of the principle of reciprocity which I propose".<ref>{{cite book |title=Proudhon's Solution of the Social Problem |editor-first=Henry |editor-last=Cohen |first=Pierre-Joseph |last=Proudhon |author-link=Pierre-Joseph Proudhon |publisher=[[Vanguard Press]] |date=1927}}</ref> Insofar as they ensure the worker's right to the full product of their labor, mutualists support [[Market (economics)|markets]] or [[artificial market]]s and [[property]] in the product of labor. However, mutualists argue for conditional titles to land, whose ownership is legitimate only so long as it remains in use or occupation (which Proudhon called ''possession''),<ref>{{cite web |last=Swartz |first=Clarence Lee |author-link=Clarence Lee Swartz |url=http://www.panarchy.org/swartz/mutualism.6.html |title=What is Mutualism? VI. Land and Rent |access-date=2014-05-05 |archive-date=2020-12-04 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20201204172903/http://www.panarchy.org/swartz/mutualism.6.html |url-status=live }}</ref> advocating [[personal property]] in place of [[private property]].<ref>{{cite book |last=Crowder |first=George |date=1991 |title=Classical Anarchism: The Political Thought of Godwin, Proudhon, Bakunin, and Kropotkin |location=Oxford |publisher=[[Clarendon Press]] |pages=85–86 |isbn=9780198277446 |quote="The ownership [anarchists oppose] is basically that which is unearned [...] including such things as interest on loans and income from rent. This is contrasted with ownership rights in those goods either produced by the work of the owner or necessary for that work, for example his dwelling-house, land and tools. Proudhon initially refers to legitimate rights of ownership of these goods as 'possession,' and although in his latter work he calls this 'property,' the conceptual distinction remains the same."}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Hargreaves |first=David H. |author-link=David Hargreaves (academic) |location=London |date=2019 |title=Beyond Schooling: An Anarchist Challenge |publisher=[[Routledge]] |pages=90–91 |isbn=9780429582363 |quote="Ironically, Proudhon did not mean literally what he said. His boldness of expression was intended for emphasis, and by 'property' he wished to be understood what he later called 'the sum of its abuses'. He was denouncing the property of the man who uses it to exploit the labour of others without any effort on his own part, property distinguished by interest and rent, by the impositions of the non-producer on the producer. Towards property regarded as 'possession' the right of a man to control his dwelling and the land and tools he needs to live, Proudhon had no hostility; indeed, he regarded it as the cornerstone of liberty, and his main criticism of the communists was that they wished to destroy it."}}</ref> However, some individualist anarchists such as [[Benjamin Tucker]] started calling possession as ''property'' or ''private property''.<ref>{{cite book|author=The Anarchist FAQ Editorial Collective|url=http://www.infoshop.org/faq/sectionG.pdf|chapter=Section G - Is individualist anarchism capitalistic?|title=An Anarchist FAQ|access-date=5 June 2020|archive-date=1 March 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210301213547/http://www.infoshop.org/faq/sectionG.pdf|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |author=The Anarchist FAQ Editorial Collective |url=http://www.spunk.org/texts/intro/faq/sp001547/append1.html |chapter=Replies to Some Errors and Distortions in Bryan Caplan's 'Anarchist Theory FAQ' version 5.2 |title=An Anarchist FAQ |access-date=24 August 2020 |quote="Tucker and Bakunin both shared Proudhon's opposition to private property (in the capitalist sense of the word), although Tucker confused this opposition (and possibly the casual reader) by talking about possession as 'property'" |archive-date=22 November 2018 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20181122010425/http://www.spunk.org/texts/intro/faq/sp001547/append1.html |url-status=live }}</ref> |
|||
[[Josiah Warren]] is widely regarded as the first American [[anarchist]]<ref name=Slate/> and the four-page weekly paper he edited during 1833, ''The Peaceful Revolutionist'', was the first anarchist periodical published.<ref name="bailie20">{{cite book |url=http://libertarian-labyrinth.org/warren/1stAmAnarch.pdf |first=William |last=Bailie |title=Josiah Warren: The First American Anarchist – A Sociological Study |access-date=17 June 2013 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120204155505/http://libertarian-labyrinth.org/warren/1stAmAnarch.pdf |archive-date=4 February 2012 |location=Boston |publisher=Small, Maynard & Co. |date=1906 |pages=20}}</ref> For American anarchist historian Eunice Minette Schuster, "[i]t is apparent [...] that Proudhonian Anarchism was to be found in the United States at least as early as 1848 and that it was not conscious of its affinity to the [[Individualist Anarchism]] of [[Josiah Warren]] and [[Stephen Pearl Andrews]]. [...] [[William B. Greene]] presented this Proudhonian Mutualism in its purest and most systematic form".<ref name="againstallauthority.org">{{cite web |url=http://www.againstallauthority.org/NativeAmericanAnarchism.html |title=''Native American Anarchism: A Study of Left-Wing American Individualism'' |first=Eunice Minette |last=Schuster |publisher=Againstallauthority.org |access-date=11 October 2013 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160214200513/http://www.againstallauthority.org/NativeAmericanAnarchism.html |archive-date=14 February 2016}}</ref> Later, the American individualist anarchist Benjamin Tucker "was against both the state and capitalism, against both oppression and exploitation. While not against the market and property he was firmly against capitalism as it was, in his eyes, a state-supported monopoly of social capital (tools, machinery, etc.) which allows owners to exploit their employees, i.e., to avoid paying workers the full value of their labour. He thought that the "labouring classes are deprived of their earnings by usury in its three forms, interest, rent and profit". Therefore, "''[[Liberty (1881–1908)|Liberty]]'' will abolish interest; it will abolish profit; it will abolish monopolistic rent; it will abolish taxation; it will abolish the exploitation of labour; it will abolish all means whereby any labourer can be deprived of any of his product". This stance puts him squarely in the libertarian socialist tradition and, unsurprisingly, Tucker referred to himself many times as a socialist and considered his philosophy to be "[a]narchistic socialism".<ref>{{cite book |url=http://infoshop.org/page/AnarchistFAQSectionG5 |chapter=Benjamin Tucker: Capitalist or Anarchist |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120107013451/http://www.infoshop.org/page/AnarchistFAQSectionG5 |archive-date=7 January 2012 |title=An Anarchist FAQ |author=Various Authors}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |quote="The economic principles of Modern Socialism are a logical deduction from the principle laid down by Adam Smith in the early chapters of his "Wealth of Nations," – namely, that labor is the true measure of price...Half a century or more after Smith enunciated the principle above stated, Socialism picked it up where he had dropped it, and in following it to its logical conclusions, made it the basis of a new economic philosophy...This seems to have been done independently by three different men, of three different nationalities, in three different languages: Josiah Warren, an American; Pierre J. Proudhon, a Frenchman; Karl Marx, a German Jew...That the work of this interesting trio should have been done so nearly simultaneously would seem to indicate that Socialism was in the air, and that the time was ripe and the conditions favorable for the appearance of this new school of thought...So far as priority of time is concerned, the credit seems to belong to Warren, the American, – a fact which should be noted by the stump orators who are so fond of declaiming against Socialism as an imported article." |author-link=Benjamin Tucker |first=Benjamin |last=Tucker |url=http://theanarchistlibrary.org/library/benjamin-tucker-individual-liberty |title=Individual Liberty |access-date=2016-10-28 |archive-date=2012-05-03 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120503100843/http://www.theanarchistlibrary.org/HTML/Benjamin_Tucker__Individual_Liberty.html |url-status=live }}</ref> |
|||
[[File:BenjaminTucker.jpg|thumb|left|[[Benjamin Tucker]], American individualist anarchist]] |
|||
[[Individualist anarchism in France|French individualist anarchist]] [[Émile Armand]] shows clearly opposition to capitalism and centralized economies when he said that the individualist anarchist "inwardly he remains refractory – fatally refractory – morally, intellectually, economically (The capitalist economy and the directed economy, the speculators and the fabricators of single systems are equally repugnant to him.)".<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.spaz.org/~dan/individualist-anarchist/library/emile-armand/life-activity.html |title="Anarchist Individualism as a Life and Activity" by Émile Armand |publisher=Spaz.org |date=1 March 2002 |access-date=11 October 2013 |archive-date=12 June 2018 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180612143925/http://www.spaz.org/~dan/individualist-anarchist/library/emile-armand/life-activity.html |url-status=live }}</ref> He argued for a pluralistic economic logic when he said that "Here and there everything happening – here everyone receiving what they need, there each one getting whatever is needed according to their own capacity. Here, [[Gift economy|gift]] and [[barter]] – one product for another; there, exchange – product for representative value. Here, the producer is the owner of the product, there, the product is put to the possession of the collectivity".<ref name="ReferenceA">{{cite web |url=http://www.revoltlib.com/?id=3762 |first=Émile |last=Armand |title=Anarchist Individualism and Amorous Comradeship |date=16 April 2020 |access-date=21 April 2020 |archive-date=24 November 2016 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20161124131919/http://theanarchistlibrary.org/library/emile-armand-anarchist-individualism-and-amorous-comradeship |url-status=live }}</ref> The Spanish individualist anarchist [[Miguel Giménez Igualada]] thought that "capitalism is an effect of government; the disappearance of government means capitalism falls from its pedestal vertiginously. [...] That which we call capitalism is not something else but a product of the State, within which the only thing that is being pushed forward is profit, good or badly acquired. And so to fight against capitalism is a pointless task, since be it [[State capitalism]] or Enterprise capitalism, as long as Government exists, exploiting capital will exist. The fight, but of consciousness, is against the State".<ref>{{cite web |quote="el capitalismo es sólo el efecto del gobierno; desaparecido el gobierno, el capitalismo cae de su pedestal vertiginosamente.... Lo que llamamos capitalismo no es otra cosa que el producto del Estado, dentro del cual lo único que se cultiva es la ganancia, bien o mal habida. Luchar, pues, contra el capitalismo es tarea inútil, porque sea Capitalismo de Estado o Capitalismo de Empresa, mientras el Gobierno exista, existirá el capital que explota. La lucha, pero de conciencias, es contra el Estado." |trans-quote="capitalism is only the effect of the government; once the government is gone, capitalism falls from its pedestal vertiginously.... What we call capitalism is nothing other than the product of the State, within which the only thing that is cultivated is profit , well or ill-gotten. Fighting, then, against capitalism is a useless task, because whether it is State Capitalism or Company Capitalism, as long as the Government exists, the capital that exploits will exist. The fight, but of conscience, is against the State. " |language=es |url=http://www.kclibertaria.comyr.com/lpdf/l125.pdf |title=Anarquismo |trans-title=Anarchism |first=Miguel Giménez |last=Igualada |author-link=Miguel Giménez Igualada |access-date=28 October 2016 |archive-date=31 January 2017 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170131205417/http://www.kclibertaria.comyr.com/lpdf/l125.pdf }}</ref> His view on [[class division]] and [[technocracy]] are as follows "Since when no one works for another, the profiteer from wealth disappears, just as government will disappear when no one pays attention to those who learned four things at universities and from that fact they pretend to govern men. Big industrial enterprises will be transformed by men in big associations in which everyone will work and enjoy the product of their work. And from those easy as well as beautiful problems anarchism deals with and he who puts them in practice and lives them are anarchists. [...] The priority which without rest an anarchist must make is that in which no one has to exploit anyone, no man to no man, since that non-exploitation will lead to the limitation of property to individual needs".<ref>{{cite web |quote="¿La propiedad? ¡Bah! No es problema. Porque cuando nadie trabaje para nadie, el acaparador de la riqueza desaparece, como ha de desaparecer el gobierno cuando nadie haga caso a los que aprendieron cuatro cosas en las universidades y por ese sólo hecho pretenden gobernar a los hombres. Porque si en la tierra de los ciegos el tuerto es rey, en donde todos ven y juzgan y disciernen, el rey estorba. Y de lo que se trata es de que no haya reyes porque todos sean hombres. Las grandes empresas industriales las transformarán los hombres en grandes asociaciones donde todos trabajen y disfruten del producto de su trabajo. Y de esos tan sencillos como hermosos problemas trata el anarquismo y al que lo cumple y vive es al que se le llama anarquista...El hincapié que sin cansancio debe hacer el anarquista es el de que nadie debe explotar a nadie, ningún hombre a ningún hombre, porque esa no-explotación llevaría consigo la limitación de la propiedad a las necesidades individuales." |trans-quote="Property? Bah! It's not a problem. Because when no one works for anyone, the hoarder of wealth disappears, as the government must disappear when no one pays attention to those who learned four things in the universities and for that sole reason they claim to govern men. Because if in the land of the blind the one-eyed man is king, where everyone sees and judges and discerns, the king is in the way. And what is involved is that there are no kings because they are all men. large industrial companies will be transformed by men into large associations where everyone works and enjoys the product of their work. And anarchism deals with those problems that are as simple as they are beautiful and the one who complies with them and lives is the one who is called an anarchist... The emphasis that the anarchist must tirelessly make is that no one should exploit anyone, no man to no man, because that non-exploitation would entail the limitation of property to individual needs." |language=es |url=http://www.kclibertaria.comyr.com/lpdf/l125.pdf|title=Anarquismo |trans-title=Anarchism |first=Miguel Giménez |last=Igualada |author-link=Miguel Giménez Igualada |access-date=28 October 2016 |archive-date=31 January 2017 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170131205417/http://www.kclibertaria.comyr.com/lpdf/l125.pdf }}</ref> |
|||
[[Left-wing market anarchism]] is a market socialist form of [[individualist anarchism]], [[left-libertarianism]] and [[libertarian socialism]]<ref>{{cite book |last1=Chartier |first1=Gary |author-link1=Gary Chartier |last2=Johnson |first2=Charles W. |author-link2=Charles W. Johnson (jurist) |date=2011 |title=Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty |location=Brooklyn, NY |publisher=Minor Compositions/Autonomedia}}</ref> associated with scholars such as [[Kevin Carson]],<ref>{{cite book |author-link=Kevin Carson |last=Carson |first=Kevin A. |date=2008 |title=Organization Theory: A Libertarian Perspective |location=Charleston, SC |publisher=BookSurge}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Carson |first=Kevin A. |author-link=Kevin Carson |date=2010 |title=The Homebrew Industrial Revolution: A Low-Overhead Manifesto |location=Charleston, SC |publisher=BookSurge}}</ref> Roderick T. Long,<ref>{{cite book |last=Long |first=Roderick T. |author-link=Roderick T. Long |date=2000 |title=Reason and Value: Aristotle versus Rand |location=Washington, DC |publisher=Objectivist Center}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |last=Long |first=Roderick T. |author-link=Roderick T. Long |date=2008 |url=http://en.liberalis.pl/2008/01/04/interview-with-roderick-long/ |title=An Interview With Roderick Long |access-date=2014-05-05 |archive-date=2020-03-27 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200327050439/https://en.liberalis.pl/2008/01/04/interview-with-roderick-long/ |url-status=live }}</ref> Charles W. Johnson,<ref>{{cite book |last=Johnson |first=Charles W. |author-link=Charles W. Johnson (jurist) |date=2008 |url=http://radgeek.com/gt/2010/03/02/liberty-equality-solidarity-toward-a-dialectical-anarchism/ |chapter=Liberty, Equality, Solidarity: Toward a Dialectical Anarchism |title=Anarchism/Minarchism: Is a Government Part of a Free Country? |editor1-last=Long |editor1-first=Roderick T. |editor1-link=Roderick T. Long |editor2-last=Machan |editor2-first=Tibor |editor2-link=Tibor Machan |location=Aldershot |publisher=Ashgate |pages=155–188 |access-date=2014-05-05 |archive-date=2022-06-26 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220626123451/https://radgeek.com/gt/2010/03/02/liberty-equality-solidarity-toward-a-dialectical-anarchism/ |url-status=live }}</ref> Brad Spangler,<ref>{{cite web |last=Spangler |first=Brad |date=15 September 2006 |url=http://bradspangler.com/blog/archives/473 |title=Market Anarchism as Stigmergic Socialism |archive-url=https://archive.today/20110510102306/http://bradspangler.com/blog/archives/473 |archive-date=10 May 2011}}</ref> [[Samuel Edward Konkin III]],<ref>{{cite book |author-link=Samuel Edward Konkin III |last=Konkin III |first=Samuel Edward |url=http://agorism.info/docs/NewLibertarianManifesto.pdf |title=The New Libertarian Manifesto |access-date=5 May 2014 |archive-date=5 June 2014 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140605094706/http://agorism.info/docs/NewLibertarianManifesto.pdf }}</ref> Sheldon Richman,<ref>{{cite web |last=Richman |first=Sheldon |date=16 July 2006 |access-date=23 June 2010 |url=http://sheldonfreeassociation.blogspot.com/2006/07/why-left-libertarian.html |title=Why Left-Libertarian? |archive-date=3 January 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200103113718/http://sheldonfreeassociation.blogspot.com/2006/07/why-left-libertarian.html |url-status=live }}</ref><ref>{{cite web |last=Richman |first=Sheldon |date=18 December 2009 |url=http://www.thefreemanonline.org/columns/tgif/workers-of-the-world-unite |title=Workers of the World Unite for a Free Market |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140722145233/http://www.thefreemanonline.org/columns/tgif/workers-of-the-world-unite |archive-date=22 July 2014 |website=Freeman Online}}</ref><ref name="LibertarianLeft">{{cite web |first=Sheldon |last=Richman |date=3 February 2011 |url=http://www.theamericanconservative.com/blog/libertarian-left/ |title=Libertarian Left: Free-market anti-capitalism, the unknown ideal |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190610075037/https://www.theamericanconservative.com/articles/libertarian-left/ |archive-date=10 June 2019 |website=[[The American Conservative]] |access-date=5 March 2012}}</ref> [[Chris Matthew Sciabarra]]<ref>{{cite book |last=Sciabarra |first=Chris Matthew |author-link=Chris Matthew Sciabarra |date=2000 |title=Total Freedom: Toward a Dialectical Libertarianism |location=University Park, PA |publisher=[[Pennsylvania State University Press]]}}</ref> and [[Gary Chartier]],<ref>{{cite book |last=Chartier |first=Gary |author-link=Gary Chartier |date=2009 |title=Economic Justice and Natural Law |location=Cambridge |publisher=[[Cambridge University Press]]}}</ref> who stress the value of radically [[free markets]], termed ''freed markets'' to distinguish them from the common conception which these libertarians believe to be riddled with [[capitalist]] and [[statist]] privileges.<ref name="marketsnotcap">{{cite book |last=Gillis |first=William |date=2011 |chapter=The Freed Market |editor1-last=Chartier |editor1-first=Gary |editor1-link=Gary Chartier |editor2-last=Johnson |editor2-first=Charles W. |editor2-link=Charles W. Johnson (jurist) |title=Markets Not Capitalism |location=Brooklyn, NY |publisher=Minor Compositions/[[Autonomedia]] |pages=19–20}}</ref> Referred to as left-wing market anarchists<ref>{{cite book |last1=Chartier |first1=Gary |author-link1=Gary Chartier |last2=Johnson |first2=Charles W. |author-link2=Charles W. Johnson (jurist) |date=2011 |title= Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty |location=Brooklyn, NY |publisher=Minor Compositions/[[Autonomedia]] |pages=1–16}}</ref> or market-oriented left-libertarians,<ref name="LibertarianLeft"/> proponents of this approach strongly affirm the [[classical liberal]] ideas of free markets and [[self-ownership]] while maintaining that taken to their logical conclusions these ideas support [[anti-capitalist]], [[anti-corporatist]], [[Social hierarchy|anti-hierarchical]], [[pro-labor]] positions in economics; [[anti-imperialism]] in foreign policy; and thoroughly liberal or radical views regarding socio-cultural issues.<ref>{{cite book |editor1-last=Chartier |editor1-first=Gary |editor1-link=Gary Chartier |editor2-last=Johnson |editor2-first=Charles W. |editor-link2=Charles W. Johnson (jurist) |title=Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty |publisher=Minor Compositions |edition=1 |date=5 November 2011}}</ref><ref>Gary Chartier has joined [[Kevin Carson]], [[Charles W. Johnson (philosopher)|Charles Johnson]], and others (echoing the language of [[Benjamin Tucker]] and [[Thomas Hodgskin]]) in maintaining that, because of its heritage and its emancipatory goals and potential, radical market anarchism should be seen – by its proponents and by others – as part of the [[socialist]] tradition, and that market anarchists can and should call themselves "socialists." See Gary Chartier, "Advocates of Freed Markets Should Oppose Capitalism," "Free-Market Anti-Capitalism?" session, annual conference, [[Association of Private Enterprise Education]] (Cæsar's Palace, Las Vegas, NV, 13 April 2010); Gary Chartier, [http://c4ss.org/content/1738 "Advocates of Freed Markets Should Embrace 'Anti-Capitalism'"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190929195335/http://c4ss.org/content/1738|date=2019-09-29}}; Gary Chartier, [http://invisiblemolotov.wordpress.com/2009/09/12/socialist-ends-market-means/ ''Socialist Ends, Market Means: Five Essays''] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190328044107/https://c4ss.org/content/1738|date=2019-03-28}}. Cp. Tucker, "Socialism."</ref> |
|||
The genealogy of contemporary left-wing market anarchism, sometimes labelled market-oriented left-libertarianism,<ref>Chris Sciabarra is the only scholar associated with this school of left-libertarianism who is skeptical about anarchism; see Sciabarra's ''Total Freedom''.</ref> overlaps to a significant degree with that of [[Steiner–Vallentyne left-libertarianism]] as the roots of that tradition are sketched in the book ''The Origins of Left-Libertarianism''.<ref>{{cite book |first1=Peter |last1=Vallentyne |author-link1=Peter Vallentyne |first2=Hillel |last2=Steiner |author-link2=Hillel Steiner |title=The origins of Left Libertarianism |publisher=[[Palgrave Macmillan]] |date=2000}}</ref> [[Carson–Long-style left-libertarianism]] is rooted in 19th-century [[Mutualism (economic theory)|mutualism]] and in the work of figures such as [[Thomas Hodgskin]], [[French Liberal School]] thinkers such as [[Gustave de Molinari]] and the [[American individualist anarchists]] Benjamin Tucker and [[Lysander Spooner]]. While with notable exceptions market-oriented libertarians after Tucker tended to ally with the political right, relationships between those libertarians and the [[New Left]] thrived in the 1960s, laying the groundwork for modern left-wing market anarchism.<ref>{{cite conference |last=Long |first=Roderick T. |author-link=Roderick T. Long |date=2006 |url=https://mises.org/daily/2099 |title=Rothbard's 'Left and Right': Forty Years Later |conference=Rothbard Memorial Lecture, Austrian Scholars Conference |access-date=2016-03-18 |archive-date=2022-06-07 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220607234938/https://mises.org/library/rothbards-left-and-right-forty-years-later |url-status=live }}</ref> Left-wing market anarchism identifies with left-libertarianism which names several related yet distinct approaches to [[politics]], society, culture and political and social theory, which stress both [[Political freedom|individual freedom]] and [[social justice]].<ref name="leftlib">Related, arguably synonymous, terms include ''libertarianism'', ''left-wing libertarianism'', ''egalitarian-libertarianism'', and ''libertarian socialism''. |
|||
* Sundstrom, William A. "[http://www.scu.edu/ethics/publications/submitted/sundstrom/Sundstrommanifesto.pdf An Egalitarian-Libertarian Manifesto] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20131029212045/http://www.scu.edu/ethics/publications/submitted/sundstrom/Sundstrommanifesto.pdf |date=2013-10-29 }}." |
|||
* {{cite book |last=Bookchin |first=Murray |author-link=Murray Bookchin |editor-last=Biehl |editor-first=Janet |editor-link=Janet Biehl |date=1997 |title=The Murray Bookchin Reader |location=New York |publisher=[[Cassell (publisher)|Cassell]] |page=170}} |
|||
* Sullivan, Mark A. (July 2003). "Why the Georgist Movement Has Not Succeeded: A Personal Response to the Question Raised by Warren J. Samuels." ''[[American Journal of Economics and Sociology]]''. 62:3. p. 612.</ref> |
|||
Unlike [[right-libertarian]]s, left-libertarians believe that neither claiming nor [[Labor theory of property|mixing one's labor]] with [[natural resources]] is enough to generate full [[private property]] rights<ref name="WhyNotIncoherent">{{cite journal |last1=Vallentyne |first1=Peter |last2=Steiner |first2=Hillel |last3=Otsuka |first3=Michael |title=Why Left-Libertarianism Is Not Incoherent, Indeterminate, or Irrelevant: A Reply to Fried |journal=[[Philosophy and Public Affairs]] |volume=33 |issue=2 |pages=201–215 |year=2005 |url=http://www.ucl.ac.uk/~uctymio/leftlibP&PA.pdf |access-date=23 July 2013 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121103160534/http://www.ucl.ac.uk/~uctymio/leftlibP%26PA.pdf |archive-date=3 November 2012 |doi=10.1111/j.1088-4963.2005.00030.x}}</ref><ref name="encyclolib">{{cite encyclopedia |last1=Narveson |first1=Jan |last2=Trenchard |first2=David |author-link1=Jan Narveson |editor-first=Ronald |editor-last=Hamowy |editor-link=Ronald Hamowy |encyclopedia=The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=yxNgXs3TkJYC |year=2008 |publisher=[[SAGE Publishing|SAGE]]; [[Cato Institute]] |location=Thousand Oaks, CA |doi=10.4135/9781412965811.n174 |isbn=978-1-4129-6580-4 |oclc=750831024 |lccn=2008009151 |pages=288–89 |title=Left Libertarianism |access-date=2016-12-02 |archive-date=2023-01-09 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230109234738/https://books.google.com/books?id=yxNgXs3TkJYC |url-status=live }}</ref> and maintain that natural resources (land, oil, gold and trees) ought to be held in some [[egalitarian]] manner, either unowned or [[owned collectively]].<ref name="encyclolib"/> Those left-libertarians who support property do so under different property norms<ref name="Schnack 2015">{{cite web |last=Schnack |first=William |date=13 November 2015 |url=https://c4ss.org/content/41572 |title=Panarchy Flourishes Under Geo-Mutualism |website=Center for a Stateless Society |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180810111658/https://c4ss.org/content/41572 |archive-date=10 August 2018 |access-date=10 August 2018}}</ref><ref name="Byas 2015">{{cite web |last=Byas |first=Jason Lee |date=25 November 2015 |url=https://c4ss.org/content/41583 |title=The Moral Irrelevance of Rent |website=Center for a Stateless Society |access-date=21 March 2020 |archive-date=28 March 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190328142055/https://c4ss.org/content/41583 |url-status=live }}</ref><ref name="Carson 2015">{{cite web |last=Carson |first=Kevin |date=8 November 2015 |url=https://c4ss.org/content/40929 |title=Are We All Mutualists? |website=Center for a Stateless Society |access-date=21 March 2020 |archive-date=28 March 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190328142104/https://c4ss.org/content/40929 |url-status=live }}</ref><ref name="Gillis 2015">Gillis, William (29 November 2015). [https://c4ss.org/content/41653 "The Organic Emergence of Property from Reputation"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200327004824/https://c4ss.org/content/41653 |date=2020-03-27 }}. Center for a Stateless Society. Retrieved 8 April 2020.</ref> and theories,<ref name="propertyownership">{{cite thesis |last=Bylund |first=Per |year=2005 |url=http://www.perbylund.com/academics_polsci_msc.pdf |title=Man and Matter: A Philosophical Inquiry into the Justification of Ownership in Land from the Basis of Self-Ownership |type=Master's |work=LUP Student Papers |publisher=[[Lund University]] |access-date=12 July 2020 |archive-date=6 September 2021 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210906074357/https://perbylund.com/academics_polsci_msc.pdf |url-status=live }}</ref><ref name="propertyrights">{{cite journal |title=Land-locked: A Critique of Carson on Property Rights |last=Long |first=Roderick T. |author-link=Roderick T. Long |volume=20 |issue=1 |year=2006 |pages=87–95 |journal=[[Journal of Libertarian Studies]] |url=https://mises.org/journals/jls/20_1/20_1_6.pdf |access-date=2020-09-06 |archive-date=2014-07-08 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140708200616/http://mises.org/journals/jls/20_1/20_1_6.pdf |url-status=live }}</ref><ref name="verhaegh">{{cite journal |last=Verhaegh |first=Marcus |year=2006 |title=Rothbard as a Political Philosopher |url=https://mises.org/journals/jls/20_4/20_4_1.pdf |journal=Journal of Libertarian Studies |volume=20 |issue=4 |page=3 |access-date=2020-09-06 |archive-date=2013-09-11 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130911003819/http://mises.org/journals/jls/20_4/20_4_1.pdf |url-status=live }}</ref> or under the condition that recompense is offered to the [[Local community|local]] or [[global community]].<ref name="encyclolib"/> |
|||
== Criticism == |
|||
[[Market abolitionism|Market abolitionists]] such as [[David McNally (professor)|David McNally]] argue in the Marxist tradition that the logic of the market inherently produces inequitable outcomes and leads to unequal exchanges, arguing that [[Adam Smith]]'s moral intent and moral philosophy espousing equal exchange was undermined by the practice of the free market he championed—the development of the [[market economy]] involved coercion, exploitation and violence that Smith's moral philosophy could not countenance. McNally criticizes market socialists for believing in the possibility of fair markets based on equal exchanges to be achieved by purging parasitical elements from the market economy such as [[private ownership]] of the [[means of production]], arguing that market socialism is an oxymoron when [[socialism]] is defined as an end to [[wage labour]].<ref>{{cite book |last=McNally |first=David |title=Against the Market: Political Economy, Market Socialism and the Marxist Critique |publisher=[[Verso Books]] |year=1993 |isbn=978-0-86091-606-2}}</ref> |
|||
== See also == |
|||
{{Wikiquote}} |
|||
{{div col|colwidth=20em}} |
|||
* [[Anti-capitalism]] |
|||
* [[Crony capitalism]] |
|||
* [[Corporatism]] |
|||
* [[Co-determination]] |
|||
** [[Worker representation on corporate boards of directors]] |
|||
* [[Cooperative]] |
|||
** [[Worker cooperative]] |
|||
* [[Distributism]] |
|||
* [[Dirigisme]] |
|||
* [[Market failure]] |
|||
* [[Monopoly]] |
|||
* [[Neoclassical economics]] |
|||
* [[Keynesian economics]] |
|||
* [[Planned economy]] |
|||
* [[Public–private partnership]] |
|||
* [[Socialist economics]] |
|||
* [[Employee stock ownership]] |
|||
* [[Liberal socialism]] |
|||
* [[Mutualism (economic theory)|Mutualism]] |
|||
* [[New Economic Mechanism]] |
|||
* [[Social market economy]] |
|||
* [[Social ownership]] |
|||
* [[Socialist-oriented market economy]] |
|||
* [[Titoism]] |
|||
* [[Types of capitalism]] |
|||
{{div col end}} |
|||
== References == |
|||
{{reflist}} |
|||
== Further reading == |
|||
* Alejandro Agafonow (2012). [https://ideas.repec.org/a/taf/revpoe/v24y2012i2p273-287.html "The Austrian Dehomogenization Debate, or the Possibility of a Hayekian Planner,"] ''Review of Political Economy'', Vol. 24, No. 02. |
|||
* [[Gary Chartier|Chartier, Gary]]; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). ''Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty.'' Brooklyn, NY:Minor Compositions/Autonomedia |
|||
* Bertell Ollman ed. (1998). ''Market Socialism: the Debate Among Socialists'', with other contributions by James Lawler, Hillel Ticktin and David Schewikart. [https://scholar.google.com/scholar?q=Bertell+Ollman+ed.+.+%22Market+Socialism%3A+the+Debate+Among+Socialists%22&hl=en&lr=&btnG=Search Preview.] |
|||
* {{cite book |last=O'Donnell |first=Steven |date=2003 |title=Introducing Entrepreneurial Activity Into Market Socialist Models |publisher=[[Auckland University Press]] |location=Auckland}} |
|||
* {{cite book |last=Roemer |first=John E. |author-link=John Roemer |editor-first=E. O. |editor-last=Wright |date=1996 |title=Equal Shares: Making Market Socialism Work |publisher=[[Verso Books]]}} |
|||
* {{cite book |last=Nove |first=Alec |author-link=Alec Nove |date=1983 |title=The Economics of Feasible Socialism |publisher=[[HarperCollins]]}} |
|||
* {{cite book |last=Miller |first=David |author-link=David Miller (political theorist) |date=1989 |title=Market, State, and Community: Theoretical Foundations of Market Socialism |publisher=[[Clarendon Press]] |location=Oxford}} |
|||
* {{cite book |last=Schweickart |first=David |author-link=David Schweickart |date=2002 |title=After Capitalism |publisher=[[Rowman & Littlefield]] |location=Lanham, Maryland}} |
|||
* {{cite book |last=Bockman |first=Johanna |date=2011 |url=https://www.sup.org/books/title/?id=21002 |title=Markets in the Name of Socialism: The Left-Wing Origins of Neoliberalism |publisher=[[Stanford University Press]] |location=Stanford|isbn=978-0-8047-7566-3 }} |
|||
==External links== |
|||
* {{Commonscatinline|Market socialism}} |
Ընթացիկ տարբերակը 17:40, 13 Օգոստոսի 2024-ի դրությամբ
Market socialism is a type of economic system involving social ownership of the means of production within the framework of a market economy. Various models for such a system exist, usually involving cooperative enterprises and sometimes a mix that includes public or private enterprises.[1][2] In contrast to the majority of historic socialist economies, which have substituted the market mechanism for some form of economic planning, market socialists wish to retain the use of supply and demand signals to guide the allocation of capital goods and the means of production.[3][4][5] Under such a system, depending on whether socially owned firms are state-owned or operated as worker cooperatives, profits may variously be used to directly remunerate employees, accrue to society at large as the source of public finance, or be distributed amongst the population in a social dividend.[6]
Market socialism can be distinguished from the concept of the mixed economy because most models of market socialism propose complete and self-regulating systems, unlike the mixed economy.[7] While social democracy aims to achieve greater economic stability and equality through policy measures such as taxes, subsidies, and social welfare programs, market socialism aims to achieve similar goals through changing patterns of enterprise ownership and management.[8]
Though the term "market socialism" only emerged in the 1920s during the socialist calculation debate,[9] a number of pre-Marx socialists, including the Ricardian socialist economists and mutualist philosophers, conceived of socialism as a natural development of the market principles of classical economics, and proposed the creation of co-operative enterprises to compete in a free-market economy. The aim of such proposals was to eliminate exploitation by allowing individuals to receive the full product of their labor, while removing the market-distorting effects of concentrating ownership and wealth in the hands of a small class of private property owners.[10]
Although sometimes described as "market socialism",[11] the Lange model is a form of market simulated planning where a central planning board allocates investment and capital goods by simulating factor market transactions, while markets allocate labor and consumer goods. The system was devised by socialist economists who believed that a socialist economy could neither function on the basis of calculation in natural units nor through solving a system of simultaneous equations for economic coordination.[12][9]
Real-world attempts to create market socialist economies have only partially implemented the measures envisioned by its theorists, but the term has sometimes been used to describe the results of various attempts at liberalization in the Eastern Bloc including Hungary's New Economic Mechanism, the economy of Yugoslavia, Perestroika, and the economic reforms of China as well as Lenin's New Economic Policy.[13]
Theoretical history
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Classical economics
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]The key theoretical basis for market socialism is the negation of the underlying expropriation of surplus value present in other modes of production. Socialist theories that favored the market date back to the Ricardian socialists and anarchist economists, who advocated a free market combined with public ownership or mutual ownership of the means of production.
Proponents of early market socialism include the Ricardian socialist economists, the classical liberal philosopher John Stuart Mill and the anarchist philosopher Pierre-Joseph Proudhon. These models of socialism entailed perfecting or improving the market mechanism and free price system by removing distortions caused by exploitation, private property and alienated labor.
This form of market socialism has been termed free-market socialism because it does not involve planners.[14][15]
John Stuart Mill
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Mill's early economic philosophy was one of free markets that he moved toward a more socialist bent, adding chapters to his Principles of Political Economy in defence of a socialist outlook, and defending some socialist causes.[16] Within this revised work he also made the radical proposal that the whole wage system be abolished in favour of a co-operative wage system. Nonetheless, some of his views on the idea of flat taxation remained,[17] albeit altered in the third edition of the Principles of Political Economy to reflect a concern for differentiating restrictions on unearned incomes which he favoured; and those on earned incomes, which he did not favour.[18]
Mill's Principles, first published in 1848, was one of the most widely read of all books on economics in the period.[19] As Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations had during an earlier period, Mill's Principles dominated economics teaching. In the case of Oxford University, it was the standard text until 1919, when it was replaced by Alfred Marshall's Principles of Economics.
In later editions of Principles of Political Economy, Mill would argue that "as far as economic theory was concerned, there is nothing in principle in economic theory that precludes an economic order based on socialist policies".[17][20]
Mill also promoted substituting capitalist businesses with worker cooperatives, writing:
The form of association, however, which if mankind continue to improve, must be expected in the end to predominate, is not that which can exist between a capitalist as chief, and work-people without a voice in the management, but the association of the labourers themselves on terms of equality, collectively owning the capital with which they carry on their operations and working under managers elected and removable by themselves.[21]
Կաղապար:Libertarian socialism sidebar
Mutualism
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Pierre-Joseph Proudhon developed a theoretical system called mutualism which attacks the legitimacy of existing property rights, subsidies, corporations, banking and rent. Proudhon envisioned a decentralized market where people would enter the market with equal power, negating wage slavery.[22] Proponents believe that cooperatives, credit unions and other forms of worker ownership would become viable without being subject to the state. Market socialism has also been used to describe some individualist anarchist works which argue that free markets help workers and weaken capitalists.[23][24]
Individualist anarchism in the United States
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]For American anarchist historian Eunice Minette Schuster, "[i]t is apparent [...] that Proudhonian Anarchism was to be found in the United States at least as early as 1848 and that it was not conscious of its affinity to the Individualist Anarchism of Josiah Warren and Stephen Pearl Andrews. [...] William B. Greene presented this Proudhonian Mutualism in its purest and most systematic form".[25] Josiah Warren is widely regarded as the first American anarchist,[26] and the four-page weekly paper he edited during 1833, The Peaceful Revolutionist, was the first anarchist periodical published,[27] an enterprise for which he built his own printing press, cast his own type, and made his own printing plates.[27]
Warren was a follower of Robert Owen and joined Owen's community at New Harmony, Indiana. Josiah Warren termed the phrase "cost the limit of price", with "cost" here referring not to monetary price paid but the labor one exerted to produce an item.[28] Therefore, "[h]e proposed a system to pay people with certificates indicating how many hours of work they did. They could exchange the notes at local time stores for goods that took the same amount of time to produce".[26] He put his theories to the test by establishing an experimental "labor for labor store" called the Cincinnati Time Store where trade was facilitated by notes backed by a promise to perform labor. The store proved successful and operated for three years after which it was closed so that Warren could pursue establishing colonies based on mutualism. These included Utopia and Modern Times. Warren said that Stephen Pearl Andrews' The Science of Society, published in 1852, was the most lucid and complete exposition of Warren's own theories.[29]
Later, Benjamin Tucker fused the economics of Warren and Proudhon and published these ideas in Liberty calling them "Anarchistic-Socialism".[30] Tucker said: "[T]he fact that one class of men are dependent for their living upon the sale of their labour, while another class of men are relieved of the necessity of labour by being legally privileged to sell something that is not labour. [...] And to such a state of things I am as much opposed as anyone. But the minute you remove privilege [...] every man will be a labourer exchanging with fellow-labourers. [...] What Anarchistic-Socialism aims to abolish is usury [...] it wants to deprive capital of its reward".[30] American individualist anarchists such as Tucker saw themselves as economic market socialists and political individualists while arguing that their "anarchistic socialism" or "individual anarchism" was "consistent Manchesterism".[31] Left-wing market anarchism is a modern branch of free-market anarchism that is based on a revival of such market socialist theories.[32][33][34][35]
Neoclassical economics
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Early 20th century
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Beginning in the early 20th century, neoclassical economic theory provided the theoretical basis for more comprehensive models of market socialism. Early neoclassical models of socialism included a role for a central planning board (CPB) in setting prices equal to marginal cost in order to achieve Pareto efficiency. Although these early models did not rely on conventional markets, they were labeled market socialist for their utilization of financial prices and calculation. Alternative outlines for market socialism involve models where socially owned enterprises or producer co-operatives operate within free markets under the criterion of profitability. In recent models proposed by American neoclassical economists, public ownership of the means of production is achieved through public ownership of equity and social control of investment.
The earliest models of neoclassical socialism were developed by Léon Walras, Enrico Barone (1908)[36][37][38] and Oskar R. Lange (c. 1936).[39] Lange and Fred M. Taylor (1929)[40] proposed that central planning boards set prices through "trial and error", making adjustments as shortages and surpluses occurred rather than relying on a free price mechanism. If there were shortages, prices would be raised; if there were surpluses, prices would be lowered.[41] Raising the prices would encourage businesses to increase production, driven by their desire to increase their profits, and in doing so eliminate the shortage. Lowering the prices would encourage businesses to curtail production to prevent losses, which would eliminate the surplus. Therefore, it would be a simulation of the market mechanism, which Lange thought would be capable of effectively managing supply and demand.[42]
Although the Lange–Lerner model was often labelled as market socialism, it is better described as market simulation because factor markets did not exist for the allocation of capital goods. The objective of the Lange–Lerner model was explicitly to replace markets with a non-market system of resource allocation.[43][44]
H. D. Dickinson published two articles proposing a form of market socialism, namely "Price Formation in a Socialist Community" (The Economic Journal 1933) and "The Problems of a Socialist Economy" (The Economic Journal 1934). Dickinson proposed a mathematical solution whereby the problems of a socialist economy could be solved by a central planning agency. The central agency would have the necessary statistics on the economy, as well as the capability of using statistics to direct production. The economy could be represented as a system of equations. Solution values for these equations could be used to price all goods at marginal cost and direct production. Hayek (1935) argued against the proposal to simulate markets with equations. Dickinson (1939) adopted the Lange-Taylor proposal to simulate markets through trial and error.
The Lange–Dickinson version of market socialism kept capital investment out of the market. Lange (1926 p65) insisted that a central planning board would have to set capital accumulation rates arbitrarily. Lange and Dickinson saw potential problems with bureaucratization in market socialism. According to Dickinson, "the attempt to check irresponsibility will tie up managers of socialist enterprises with so much red tape and bureaucratic regulation that they will lose all initiative and independence" (Dickinson 1938, p. 214). In The Economics of Control: Principles of Welfare Economics (1944), Abba Lerner admitted that capital investment would be politicized in market socialism.
Late 20th century and early 21st century
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Economists active in the former Yugoslavia, including Czech-born Jaroslav Vaněk and Croat-born Branko Horvat, promoted a model of market socialism dubbed the Illyrian model, where firms were socially owned by their employees and structured around workers' self-management, competing with each other in open and free markets.
American economists in the latter half of the 20th century developed models based such as coupon socialism (by the economist John Roemer) and economic democracy (by the philosopher David Schweickart).
Pranab Bardhan and John Roemer proposed a form of market socialism where there was a stock market that distributed shares of the capital stock equally among citizens. In this stock market, there is no buying or selling of stocks that leads to negative externalities associated with a concentration of capital ownership. The Bardhan and Roemer model satisfied the main requirements of both socialism (workers own all the factors of production, not just labour) and market economies (prices determine efficient allocation of resources). New Zealand economist Steven O'Donnell expanded on the Bardhan and Roemer model and decomposed the capital function in a general equilibrium system to take account of entrepreneurial activity in market socialist economies. O'Donnell (2003) set up a model that could be used as a blueprint for transition economies and the results suggested that although market socialist models were inherently unstable in the long term, they would provide in the short term the economic infrastructure necessary for a successful transition from planned to market economies.
In the early 21st century, the Marxian economist Richard D. Wolff refocused Marxian economics giving it a microfoundational focus. The core idea was that transition from capitalism to socialism required the reorganization of the enterprise from a top-down hierarchical capitalist model to a model where all key enterprise decisions (what, how, and where to produce and what to do with outputs) were made on a one-worker, one vote basis. Wolff called them workers self-directed enterprises (WSDEs). How they would interact with one another and with consumers was left open to democratic social decisions and could entail markets or planning, or likely mixtures of both.
Advocates of market socialism such as Jaroslav Vaněk argue that genuinely free markets are not possible under conditions of private ownership of productive property. Instead, he contends that the class differences and inequalities in income and power that result from private ownership enable the interests of the dominant class to skew the market to their favor, either in the form of monopoly and market power, or by utilizing their wealth and resources to legislate government policies that benefit their specific business interests. Additionally, Vaněk states that workers in a socialist economy based on cooperative and self-managed enterprises have stronger incentives to maximize productivity because they would receive a share of the profits (based on the overall performance of their enterprise) in addition to receiving their fixed wage or salary. The stronger incentives to maximize productivity that he conceives as possible in a socialist economy based on cooperative and self-managed enterprises might be accomplished in a free-market economy if employee-owned companies were the norm as envisioned by various thinkers including Louis O. Kelso and James S. Albus.[45]
Giacomo Corneo, Professor of Public Finance and Social Policy at the Free University of Berlin, espouses an "updated version of market socialism" where large firms would be publicly owned (though by no more than 51% share),[46] which would allow the government to distribute a social dividend, while the rest of the firms would be privately owned and subject to regulations to protect employees, consumers and environment.[47]
Matt Bruenig advocates for a version of market socialism he calls "funds socialism," which involves sovereign wealth funds acquiring shares of private enterprises to socialize ownership and control of firms.[48][49] Bruenig claims that this form of market socialism is similar to that advocated by Yanis Varoufakis, Rudolf Meidner, and John Roemer.[49]
Anti-equilibrium economics
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Another form of market socialism has been promoted by critics of central planning and generally of neoclassical general equilibrium theory. The most notable of these economists were Alec Nove and János Kornai. In particular, in 1983 Nove proposed what he called "feasible socialism",[50] a mixed economy consisting of state-run enterprises, autonomous publicly owned firms, cooperatives and small-scale private enterprise operating in a market economy that included a role for macroeconomic planning.[51]
In practice
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]A number of market socialist elements have existed in various economies. The economy of Yugoslavia was widely considered to have been a form of market-based socialism, based on socially-owned cooperatives, workers' self-management, and market allocation of capital.[52] Some of the economic reforms introduced during the Prague Spring by Alexander Dubček, the leader of Czechoslovakia, included elements of market socialism.[53]
Likewise, Vietnam's socialist-oriented market economy is self-described as market socialist. It has an extremely high prevalence of cooperatives, especially in agriculture and retail, with the continued state ownership of the commanding heights of the economy.[54] Cooperative businesses in Vietnam are also incentivized and supported by the government, receiving many benefits that private companies do not.[55]
Peter Drucker described the United States system of regulated pension funds providing capital to financial markets as "pension fund socialism".[56] William H. Simon characterized pension fund socialism as "a form of market socialism", concluding that it was promising but perhaps with prospects more limited than those envisioned by its enthusiasts.[57]
The economy of Cuba under the rule of Raúl Castro has been described as attempting market socialist reforms.[58] Similarly, the economy of Libya under Muammar Gaddafi could be described as a form of market socialism as Muammar Gaddafi's Third International Theory shared many similarities with Yugoslav self-management.[59][60]
Policies similar to the market socialist proposal of a social dividend and basic income scheme have been implemented on the basis of public ownership of natural resources in Alaska (Alaska Permanent Fund) and in Norway (the Government Pension Fund of Norway).[48]
After a decade of political, social and economic turmoil following the Cultural Revolution, China began its reform and opening-up in 1978 and formally amended its constitution in adopting the socialist market economy as the country's economic system in 1993.[61]
Relation to political ideologies
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Marxism–Leninism
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]The phrase market socialism has occasionally been used in reference to any attempt by a Soviet-type planned economy to introduce market elements into its economic system. In this sense, market socialism was first attempted during the 1920s in the Soviet Union as the New Economic Policy (NEP) before being abandoned. Later, elements of market socialism were introduced in Hungary (nicknamed goulash communism), Czechoslovakia (sloganized as socialism with a human face), Yugoslavia (known as Titoism) in the 1970s and 1980s. The contemporary Economy of Belarus has been described as a market socialist system. The Soviet Union attempted to introduce a market system with its perestroika reforms under Mikhail Gorbachev. During the later stages there was talk within top circles that the Soviet Union should move toward a market-based socialist system.
Historically, these kinds of market socialist systems attempt to retain state ownership of the commanding heights of the economy such as heavy industry, energy and infrastructure while introducing decentralised decision making and giving local managers more freedom to make decisions and respond to market demands. Market socialist systems also allow private ownership and entrepreneurship in the service and other secondary economic sectors. The market is allowed to determine prices for consumer goods and agricultural products, and farmers are allowed to sell all or some of their products on the open market and keep some or all of the profit as an incentive to increase and improve production.
Both the Eastern European and Chinese socialist approaches to market reforms assume that a "market economy" is not necessarily a capitalist market economy, and that a socialist economy is not necessarily a planned economy.[62] This view draws support from Karl Marx's observations that markets existed under historical modes of production such as the Roman slave market economy and feudal markets.[62]
Socialism with Chinese characteristics
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]The term market socialism has been used to refer to reformed economic systems in Marxist–Leninist states, most notably in reference to the contemporary economy of the People's Republic of China, where a free price system is used for the allocation of capital goods in both the state and private sectors. However, Chinese political and economic proponents of the socialist market economy do not consider it to be a form of market socialism in the neoclassical sense[63] and many Western economists and political scientists question the degree to which this model constitutes a form of market socialism, often preferring to describe it as state capitalism.[64]
Although similar in name, market socialism differs markedly from the socialist market economy and socialist-oriented market economy models practiced in the contemporary People's Republic of China and Socialist Republic of Vietnam, respectively. Officially these economic systems represent market economies that are in the long-term process of transition toward socialism.[65] Key differences between models of market socialism and the Chinese and Vietnamese models include the role of private investment in enterprises, the lack of a social dividend or basic income system to equitably distribute state profits among the population and the existence and role of financial markets in the Chinese model—markets which are absent in the market socialist literature.[64]
The Chinese experience with socialism with Chinese characteristics is frequently referred to as a socialist market economy where the commanding heights are state-owned, but a substantial portion of both the state and private sectors of economy are governed by market practices, including a stock exchange for trading equity and the utilization of indirect macroeconomic market mechanisms (i.e. fiscal, monetary and industrial policies) to influence the economy in the same manner governments affect the economy in capitalist economies. The market is the arbitrator for most economic activity, with economic planning being relegated to macro-economic government indicative planning that does not encompass the microeconomic decision-making that is left to the individual organizations and state-owned enterprises. This model includes a significant amount of privately owned firms that operate as a business for profit, but only for consumer goods and services.[66]
In the Chinese system, directive planning based on mandatory output requirements and quotas were displaced by market mechanisms for most of the economy, including both the state and private sectors, although the government engages in indicative planning for large state enterprises.[66] In comparison with the Soviet-type planned economy, the Chinese socialist market model is based on the corporatization of state institutions, transforming them into joint-stock companies. As of 2008, there were 150 state-owned corporations directly under the central government.[67] These state-owned corporations have been reformed and become increasingly dynamic and a major source of revenue for the state in 2008,[68][69] leading the economic recovery in 2009 during the wake of the global financial crises.[70]
This economic model is defended from a Marxist–Leninist perspective which states that a planned socialist economy can only emerge after first developing the basis for socialism through the establishment of a market economy and commodity-exchange economy; and that socialism would only emerge after this stage has exhausted its historical necessity and gradually transforms itself into socialism.[63] Proponents of this model argue that the economic system of the former Soviet Union and its satellite states attempted to go from a natural economy to a planned economy by decree, without passing through the necessary market economy phase of development.[71]
Democratic socialism
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Կաղապար:Main articles Some democratic socialists advocate forms of market socialism, some of which are based on self-management. Others advocate for a non-market participatory economy based on decentralized economic planning.[72]
Anarchism
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]The French philosopher Pierre-Joseph Proudhon is the first person to call himself an anarchist and considered among its most influential theorists. Proudhon is considered by many to be the "father of anarchism".[73] Proudhon became a member of the French Parliament after the French Revolution of 1848, whereon he referred to himself as a federalist.[74] Proudhon's best-known assertion is that "Property is theft!", contained in his first major work What Is Property?, published in 1840. The book's publication attracted the attention of the French authorities. It also attracted the scrutiny of Karl Marx, who started a correspondence with Proudhon. The two influenced each other and met in Paris while Marx was exiled there. Their friendship finally ended when Marx responded to Proudhon's The Philosophy of Poverty with the provocatively titled The Poverty of Philosophy. The dispute became one of the sources of the split between the anarchist and Marxist wings of the International Working Men's Association. Mutualism is an anarchist school of thought and market socialist economic theory that advocates a socialist society where each person possess a means of production, either individually or collectively, with trade representing equivalent amounts of labor in the free market.[75] Integral to the scheme was the establishment of a mutual-credit bank that would lend to producers at a minimal interest rate, just high enough to cover administration.[76] Mutualism is based on a labor theory of value which holds that when labor or its product is sold it ought to receive in exchange goods or services embodying "the amount of labor necessary to produce an article of exactly similar and equal utility".[77]
Mutualism originated from the writings of Proudhon. Mutualists oppose the idea of individuals receiving an income through loans, investments and rent as they believe these individuals are not laboring. Although opposed this type of income, Proudhon expressed that he had never intended "to forbid or suppress, by sovereign decree, ground rent and interest on capital. I think that all these manifestations of human activity should remain free and voluntary for all: I ask for them no modifications, restrictions or suppressions, other than those which result naturally and of necessity from the universalization of the principle of reciprocity which I propose".[78] Insofar as they ensure the worker's right to the full product of their labor, mutualists support markets or artificial markets and property in the product of labor. However, mutualists argue for conditional titles to land, whose ownership is legitimate only so long as it remains in use or occupation (which Proudhon called possession),[79] advocating personal property in place of private property.[80][81] However, some individualist anarchists such as Benjamin Tucker started calling possession as property or private property.[82][83]
Josiah Warren is widely regarded as the first American anarchist[26] and the four-page weekly paper he edited during 1833, The Peaceful Revolutionist, was the first anarchist periodical published.[27] For American anarchist historian Eunice Minette Schuster, "[i]t is apparent [...] that Proudhonian Anarchism was to be found in the United States at least as early as 1848 and that it was not conscious of its affinity to the Individualist Anarchism of Josiah Warren and Stephen Pearl Andrews. [...] William B. Greene presented this Proudhonian Mutualism in its purest and most systematic form".[84] Later, the American individualist anarchist Benjamin Tucker "was against both the state and capitalism, against both oppression and exploitation. While not against the market and property he was firmly against capitalism as it was, in his eyes, a state-supported monopoly of social capital (tools, machinery, etc.) which allows owners to exploit their employees, i.e., to avoid paying workers the full value of their labour. He thought that the "labouring classes are deprived of their earnings by usury in its three forms, interest, rent and profit". Therefore, "Liberty will abolish interest; it will abolish profit; it will abolish monopolistic rent; it will abolish taxation; it will abolish the exploitation of labour; it will abolish all means whereby any labourer can be deprived of any of his product". This stance puts him squarely in the libertarian socialist tradition and, unsurprisingly, Tucker referred to himself many times as a socialist and considered his philosophy to be "[a]narchistic socialism".[85][86]
French individualist anarchist Émile Armand shows clearly opposition to capitalism and centralized economies when he said that the individualist anarchist "inwardly he remains refractory – fatally refractory – morally, intellectually, economically (The capitalist economy and the directed economy, the speculators and the fabricators of single systems are equally repugnant to him.)".[87] He argued for a pluralistic economic logic when he said that "Here and there everything happening – here everyone receiving what they need, there each one getting whatever is needed according to their own capacity. Here, gift and barter – one product for another; there, exchange – product for representative value. Here, the producer is the owner of the product, there, the product is put to the possession of the collectivity".[88] The Spanish individualist anarchist Miguel Giménez Igualada thought that "capitalism is an effect of government; the disappearance of government means capitalism falls from its pedestal vertiginously. [...] That which we call capitalism is not something else but a product of the State, within which the only thing that is being pushed forward is profit, good or badly acquired. And so to fight against capitalism is a pointless task, since be it State capitalism or Enterprise capitalism, as long as Government exists, exploiting capital will exist. The fight, but of consciousness, is against the State".[89] His view on class division and technocracy are as follows "Since when no one works for another, the profiteer from wealth disappears, just as government will disappear when no one pays attention to those who learned four things at universities and from that fact they pretend to govern men. Big industrial enterprises will be transformed by men in big associations in which everyone will work and enjoy the product of their work. And from those easy as well as beautiful problems anarchism deals with and he who puts them in practice and lives them are anarchists. [...] The priority which without rest an anarchist must make is that in which no one has to exploit anyone, no man to no man, since that non-exploitation will lead to the limitation of property to individual needs".[90]
Left-wing market anarchism is a market socialist form of individualist anarchism, left-libertarianism and libertarian socialism[91] associated with scholars such as Kevin Carson,[92][93] Roderick T. Long,[94][95] Charles W. Johnson,[96] Brad Spangler,[97] Samuel Edward Konkin III,[98] Sheldon Richman,[99][100][101] Chris Matthew Sciabarra[102] and Gary Chartier,[103] who stress the value of radically free markets, termed freed markets to distinguish them from the common conception which these libertarians believe to be riddled with capitalist and statist privileges.[104] Referred to as left-wing market anarchists[105] or market-oriented left-libertarians,[101] proponents of this approach strongly affirm the classical liberal ideas of free markets and self-ownership while maintaining that taken to their logical conclusions these ideas support anti-capitalist, anti-corporatist, anti-hierarchical, pro-labor positions in economics; anti-imperialism in foreign policy; and thoroughly liberal or radical views regarding socio-cultural issues.[106][107]
The genealogy of contemporary left-wing market anarchism, sometimes labelled market-oriented left-libertarianism,[108] overlaps to a significant degree with that of Steiner–Vallentyne left-libertarianism as the roots of that tradition are sketched in the book The Origins of Left-Libertarianism.[109] Carson–Long-style left-libertarianism is rooted in 19th-century mutualism and in the work of figures such as Thomas Hodgskin, French Liberal School thinkers such as Gustave de Molinari and the American individualist anarchists Benjamin Tucker and Lysander Spooner. While with notable exceptions market-oriented libertarians after Tucker tended to ally with the political right, relationships between those libertarians and the New Left thrived in the 1960s, laying the groundwork for modern left-wing market anarchism.[110] Left-wing market anarchism identifies with left-libertarianism which names several related yet distinct approaches to politics, society, culture and political and social theory, which stress both individual freedom and social justice.[111]
Unlike right-libertarians, left-libertarians believe that neither claiming nor mixing one's labor with natural resources is enough to generate full private property rights[112][113] and maintain that natural resources (land, oil, gold and trees) ought to be held in some egalitarian manner, either unowned or owned collectively.[113] Those left-libertarians who support property do so under different property norms[114][115][116][117] and theories,[118][119][120] or under the condition that recompense is offered to the local or global community.[113]
Criticism
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Market abolitionists such as David McNally argue in the Marxist tradition that the logic of the market inherently produces inequitable outcomes and leads to unequal exchanges, arguing that Adam Smith's moral intent and moral philosophy espousing equal exchange was undermined by the practice of the free market he championed—the development of the market economy involved coercion, exploitation and violence that Smith's moral philosophy could not countenance. McNally criticizes market socialists for believing in the possibility of fair markets based on equal exchanges to be achieved by purging parasitical elements from the market economy such as private ownership of the means of production, arguing that market socialism is an oxymoron when socialism is defined as an end to wage labour.[121]
See also
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]- Anti-capitalism
- Crony capitalism
- Corporatism
- Co-determination
- Cooperative
- Distributism
- Dirigisme
- Market failure
- Monopoly
- Neoclassical economics
- Keynesian economics
- Planned economy
- Public–private partnership
- Socialist economics
- Employee stock ownership
- Liberal socialism
- Mutualism
- New Economic Mechanism
- Social market economy
- Social ownership
- Socialist-oriented market economy
- Titoism
- Types of capitalism
References
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]- ↑ Schweickart, David; Lawler, James; Tickten, Hillel; Ollman, Bertell (2016-04-22). Market Socialism: The Debate Among Socialists. Taylor & Francis. էջ 105. «....it is important to realize that the school of thinking calls itself "market socialism" is further divisible along three different lines: (1) whether its goal, market socialism, involves only worker-owned enterprises, or a mix of enterprises some worker-owned, some privately-owned, some nationalized, etc. (2) whether market socialism will eventually by followed by communism...»
- ↑ Corneo, Giacomo (2017). Is Capitalism Obsolete? A Journey through Alternative Economic Systems. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. էջեր 192–197.
- ↑ O'Hara, Phillip (September 2000). Encyclopedia of Political Economy. Vol. 2. Routledge. էջ 71. ISBN 978-0415241878. «Market socialism is the general designation for a number of models of economic systems. On the one hand, the market mechanism is utilized to distribute economic output, to organize production and to allocate factor inputs. On the other hand, the economic surplus accrues to society at large rather than to a class of private (capitalist) owners, through some form of collective, public or social ownership of capital.»
- ↑ Buchanan, Alan E. (1985). Ethics, Efficiency and the Market. Oxford University Press. էջեր 104–105. ISBN 978-0-8476-7396-4.
- ↑ Gregory, Paul R.; Stuart, Robert C. (2003). Comparing Economic Systems in the Twenty-First Century. էջ 142. ISBN 0-618-26181-8. «It is an economic system that combines social ownership of capital with market allocation of capital...The state owns the means of production, and returns accrue to society at large.»
- ↑ Marangos, John (2004). «Social Dividend Versus Basic Income Guarantee in Market Socialism». International Journal of Political Economy. 34 (3): 20–40. doi:10.1080/08911916.2004.11042930. JSTOR 40470892. S2CID 153267388.
- ↑ Bockman, Johanna (2011). Markets in the name of Socialism: The Left-Wing origins of Neoliberalism. Stanford University Press. ISBN 978-0-8047-7566-3. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2020-11-28-ին. Վերցված է 2020-12-25-ին.
- ↑ Roosevelt III, Franklin Delano; Belkin, David (1994). Why Market Socialism?. M.E. Sharpe, Inc. էջ 314. ISBN 978-1-56324-465-0. «Social democracy achieves greater egalitarianism via ex post government taxes and subsidies, where market socialism does so via ex ante changes in patterns of enterprise ownership.»
- ↑ 9,0 9,1 Steele, David Ramsay (September 1999). From Marx to Mises: Post Capitalist Society and the Challenge of Economic Calculation. Open Court. էջ 177. ISBN 978-0875484495. «It was in the early 1920s that the expression 'market socialism' (marktsozialismus) became commonplace. A special term was considered necessary to distinguish those socialists prepared to accept some role for factor markets from the now mainstream socialists who were not.»
- ↑ McNally, David (1993). Against the Market: Political Economy, Market Socialism and the Marxist Critique. Verso Books. էջ 44. ISBN 978-0-86091-606-2. «[...] [B]y the 1820s, 'Smithian' apologists for industrial capitalism confronted 'Smithian' socialists in a vigorous, and often venomous, debate over political economy.»
- ↑ Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1996). Whither Socialism?. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. ISBN 9780262691826.
- ↑ Roemer, John (1 January 1994). A Future for Socialism. Harvard University Press. էջ 28. ISBN 978-0674339460. «The first stage was marked by the realization by socialists that prices must be used for economic calculation under socialism; accounting in some kind of 'natural unit,' such as the amount of energy or labor commodities embodied, simply would not work. The second stage was characterized by the view that it would be possible to calculate the prices at which general equilibrium would be reached in a socialist economy by solving a complicated system of simultaneous equations [...]. The third stage was marked by the realization, by Lange and others, that markets would indeed be required to find the socialist equilibrium [...].»
- ↑ Ackerman, Seth. «The Forgotten Vision of Market Socialism». Institute for New Economic Thinking (անգլերեն). Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2023-08-21-ին. Վերցված է 2023-08-21-ին.
- ↑ Hunt, E. K. (20 November 2002). Property and Prophets: the evolution of economic institutions and ideologies. M. E. Sharpe. էջ 72. ISBN 978-0-7656-0609-9. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 8 February 2024-ին. Վերցված է 10 August 2021-ին.
- ↑ Carson, Kevin (16 July 2006). «J.S. Mill, Market Socialist». Mutualist Blog: Free Market Anti-Capitalism. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 6 March 2019-ին. Վերցված է 2 March 2016-ին.
- ↑ Mill, John Stuart (2004). Bentham, Jeremy; Ryan, Alan (eds.). Utilitarianism and other essays. London: Penguin Books. էջ 11. ISBN 978-0-14-043272-5.
- ↑ 17,0 17,1 Wilson, Fred, ed. (2007). «John Stuart Mill: Political Economy». Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy. Stanford University. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 6 January 2010-ին. Վերցված է 4 May 2009-ին.
- ↑ Mill, John Stuart (1852). «On The General Principles of Taxation, V.2.14». Principles of Political Economy. [Online Library of Liberty]. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 7 May 2019-ին. Վերցված է 6 January 2013-ին. (3rd edition; the passage about flat taxation was altered by the author in this edition, which is acknowledged in this online edition's footnote 8. This sentence replaced in the 3rd ed. a sentence of the original: "It is partial taxation, which is a mild form of robbery".
- ↑ Ekelund, Robert B. Jr.; Hébert, Robert F. (1997). A history of economic theory and method (4th ed.). Long Grove, Illinois: Waveland Press. էջ 172. ISBN 978-1-57766-381-2.
- ↑ Baum, Bruce. (2007). «J. S. Mill and Liberal Socialism». In Urbanati, Nadia; Zachars, Alex (eds.). J. S. Mill's Political Thought: A Bicentennial Reassessment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. «Mill, in contrast, advances a form of liberal democratic socialism for the enlargement of freedom as well as to realize social and distributive justice. He offers a powerful account of economic injustice and justice that is centered on his understanding of freedom and its conditions»
- ↑ Mill, John Stuart (1909). Ashley, William James (ed.). Principles of Political Economy with some of their Applications to Social Philosophy (7th ed.). London: Longmans, Green and Co. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2016-03-07-ին. Վերցված է 2017-12-27-ին.
- ↑ Carson, Kevin (19 January 2006). «Eugene Plawiuk on Anarchist Socialism». Mutualist Blog: Free Market Anti-Capitalism. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 27 March 2019-ին. Վերցված է 2 March 2016-ին.
- ↑ Bookchin, Murray (1992). The Ghost of Anarcho-Syndicalism.
- ↑ Graham, Robert. The General Idea of Proudhon's Revolution. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2021-06-29-ին. Վերցված է 2021-08-03-ին.
- ↑ Schuster, Eunice Minette. «Native American Anarchism: A Study of Left-Wing American Individualism». againstallauthority.org. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից 14 February 2016-ին. Վերցված է 2 March 2016-ին.
- ↑ 26,0 26,1 26,2 Palmer, Brian (29 December 2010). «What do anarchists want from us?». Slate.com. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 1 September 2011-ին. Վերցված է 8 October 2013-ին.
- ↑ 27,0 27,1 27,2 Bailie, William (1906). Josiah Warren: The First American Anarchist – A Sociological Study (PDF). Boston: Small, Maynard & Co. էջ 20. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից (PDF) 4 February 2012-ին. Վերցված է 17 June 2013-ին.
- ↑ "A watch has a cost and a value. The COST consists of the amount of labor bestowed on the mineral or natural wealth, in converting it into metals...". Warren, Josiah. Equitable Commerce
- ↑ Madison, Charles A. (January 1945). «Anarchism in the United States». Journal of the History of Ideas. 6 (1): 53. doi:10.2307/2707055. JSTOR 2707055.
- ↑ 30,0 30,1 Tucker, Benjamin. Instead of a Book. էջ 404.
- ↑ Tucker, Benjamin (1926). Individual Liberty: Selections from the Writings of Benjamin R. Tucker. New York: Vanguard Press. էջեր 1–19.
- ↑ Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W., eds. (5 November 2011). Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty (1 ed.). Minor Compositions.
- ↑ Chartier, Gary (13 April 2010). Advocates of Freed Markets Should Oppose Capitalism. Free-Market Anti-Capitalism?. Cæsar's Palace, Las Vegas, NV: Association of Private Enterprise Education.
- ↑ Chartier, Gary. «Advocates of Freed Markets Should Embrace 'Anti-Capitalism'». Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2019-09-29-ին. Վերցված է 2014-05-05-ին.
- ↑ Chartier, Gary; Tulsa Alliance of the Libertarian Left (12 September 2009). Socialist Ends, Market Means: Five Essays. Center for a Stateless Society. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 28 March 2019-ին. Վերցված է 5 May 2014-ին.
- ↑ Caffé, F. (1987). «Barone, Enrico». The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. Vol. 1. Palgrave Macmillan. էջ 195. ISBN 978-1-56159-197-8.
- ↑ Barone, Enrico. «Il Ministro della Produzione nello Stato Collettivista» [The Ministry of Production in the Collectivist State]. Giornale degli Economisti (իտալերեն). 2: 267–93.
- ↑ Hayek, Friedrich, ed. (1935). Collectivist Economic Planning. էջեր 245–290. ISBN 978-0-7100-1506-8.
- ↑ Hahnel, Robin (2005). Economic Justice and Democracy. Routledge. էջ 170. ISBN 978-0-415-93344-5. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2024-02-08-ին. Վերցված է 2021-08-10-ին.
- ↑ Taylor, Fred M. (1929). «The Guidance of Production in a Socialist State». The American Economic Review. 19 (1): 1–8. JSTOR 1809581.
- ↑ Skousen, Mark (2001). Making Modern Economics. M.E. Sharpe. էջեր 414–415. ISBN 978-0-7656-0479-8.
- ↑ Kornai, János (1992). The Socialist System: the political economy of communism. Oxford University Press. էջ 476. ISBN 978-0-19-828776-6.
- ↑ Steele, David Ramsay (September 1999). From Marx to Mises: Post Capitalist Society and the Challenge of Economic Calculation. Open Court. էջ 151. ISBN 978-0875484495. «Finally, there is the curious circumstance that Lange's system is widely hailed as a pioneering effort in the theory of market socialism, when it is demonstrably no such thing: even the name 'market socialism' predates Lange, and Lange's system is explicitly a proposal to replace the market with a non-market system.»
- ↑ Aslund, Anders (1992). Market Socialism Or the Restoration of Capitalism?. Cambridge University Press. էջ 20. ISBN 9780521411936. «Usually Oskar Lange is regarded as the originator of the concept of market socialism, in spite of the fact that he never spoke of market socialism and would not have been the first if he had. In fact, Lange's model involves only a partial market simulation for the trial-and-error iterative construction of a central plan, which belongs to the set of decentralization procedures in central planning.»
- ↑ Perkins, Albert. «Cooperative Economics: An Interview with Jaroslav Vanek». New Renaissance Magazine. Vol. 5, no. 1. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 17 August 2021-ին. Վերցված է 17 March 2011-ին.
- ↑ Corneo, Giacomo (2017). s Capitalism Obsolete? A Journey through Alternative Economic Systems. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. «...the federal shareholder should retain only 51 percent of their shares. Private ownership of the remaining 29% percent has a key role to play in creating an incentive structure that leads those firms to maximize profits.»
- ↑ «Towards Shareholder Socialism? | An interview with Giacomo Corneo». Medium. 8 December 2018. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 28 January 2022-ին. Վերցված է 28 January 2022-ին. «The blueprint has private ownership in the means of production with respect to small- and medium-sized firms, because we think that individualism at the level of entrepreneurial initiatives is an important ingredient for economic dynamism. But all large firms would be in public ownership, and this would be the key difference with respect to today's economic system.»
- ↑ 48,0 48,1 Bruenig, Matt (28 September 2018). «Common Wealth: workers' ownership in the history of socialism». Verso (անգլերեն). Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2023-08-11-ին. Վերցված է 2023-08-11-ին.
- ↑ 49,0 49,1 Bruenig, Matt (February 11, 2017). «Nickel-and-Dime Socialism». Medium. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից October 14, 2018-ին. Վերցված է October 14, 2018-ին.
- ↑ Nove, A. (1983), The Economics of Feasible Socialism, Unwin Hyman
- ↑ «Feasible Socialism: Market or Plan – Or Both». Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից 20 November 2008-ին. Վերցված է 14 November 2023-ին.
- ↑ Gagnon, V.P. Jr. (Summer 1991). «Yugoslavia: Prospects for Stability». Foreign Affairs. 70 (3): 17–35. doi:10.2307/20044816. JSTOR 20044816. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2021-08-24-ին. Վերցված է 24 August 2021-ին.
- ↑ Golan, Galia (1971). Reform Rule in Czechoslovakia: The Dubcek Era 1968–1969. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521085861.
- ↑ Luong Minh Cu (13 August 2019). «Key role of the state economic sector in Vietnam's socialist-oriented market economy undeniable». National Defence Journal. Վերցված է 5 August 2020-ին.(չաշխատող հղում)
- ↑ «Vietnam to release white book on cooperatives». VietNam Breaking News. 10 March 2020. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 8 July 2020-ին. Վերցված է 5 August 2020-ին.
- ↑ Drucker, Peter Ferdinand (1976). The Unseen Revolution: How Pension Fund Socialism Came to America. HarperCollins. ISBN 9780060110970.
- ↑ Simon, William H. (1995). «Prospects for Pension Fund Socialism». In McCahery, J.; Picciotto, Sol; Scott, Colin (eds.). Corporate Control and Accountability: Changing Structures and the Dynamics. Oxford University Press. էջ 167. ISBN 9780198259909.
- ↑ «Cuba inches towards market socialism». BBC News. 27 March 2011. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 29 September 2023-ին. Վերցված է 30 December 2019-ին.
- ↑ «Lybia» (PDF). Revolutionary Committees Movement. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից (PDF) 2023-04-26-ին. Վերցված է 2020-07-08-ին.
- ↑ Iveković, Ivan (3 April 2009). «Libijska džamahirija između prošlosti i sadašnjosti - 1. dio» [Libyan Jamahiriya between past and present - Part 1]. H-Alter (խորվաթերեն). Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից 1 February 2014-ին. Վերցված է 5 August 2020-ին.
- ↑ «China: Is its 'socialist market economy' era over? – DW – 03/29/2023». dw.com (անգլերեն). Վերցված է 2024-07-01-ին.
- ↑ 62,0 62,1 Boer, Roland (2021-10-01). «From Belgrade to Beijing : Comparing Socialist Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe and China». World Review of Political Economy. 12: 299. doi:10.13169/worlrevipoliecon.12.3.0296. ISSN 2042-8928. S2CID 247967541.
- ↑ 63,0 63,1 Zhongqiao, Duan. «Market Economy and Socialist Road» (PDF). Արխիվացված (PDF) օրիգինալից 10 July 2012-ին. Վերցված է 4 February 2016-ին.
- ↑ Karadjis, Michael. «Socialism and the market: China and Vietnam compared». Links International Journal for Socialist Renewal. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 10 April 2019-ին. Վերցված է 20 March 2013-ին.
- ↑ 66,0 66,1 Chow, Gregory C. (24–25 March 2004). The Role of Planning in China's Market Economy (PDF). International Conference on China's Planning System Reform. Asian Development Bank. Beijing. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից (PDF) 26 May 2004-ին.
- ↑ «Reassessing China's State-Owned Enterprises». Forbes. 8 July 2008. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 11 April 2019-ին. Վերցված է 4 September 2017-ին.
- ↑ «InfoViewer: China's champions: Why state ownership is no longer proving a dead hand». Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից 11 July 2011-ին. Վերցված է 2 June 2010-ին.
- ↑ Ralston, David A.; Terpstra-Tong, Jane; Terpstra, Robert H.; Wang, Xueli. «Today's State-Owned Enterprises of China: Are They Dying Dinosaurs or Dynamic Dynamos?» (PDF). Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից (PDF) 20 July 2011-ին.
- ↑ «China grows faster amid worries». BBC News. 16 July 2009. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 7 September 2019-ին. Վերցված է 12 May 2010-ին.
- ↑ Vuong, Quan-Hoang (February 2010). Financial Markets in Vietnam's Transition Economy: Facts, Insights, Implications. Saarbrücken, Germany: VDM Publishing. ISBN 978-3-639-23383-4.
- ↑ Anderson, Gary L.; Herr, Kathryn G. (2007). Encyclopedia of Activism and Social Justice. SAGE Publications, inc. էջ 448. ISBN 978-1412918121. «Some have endorsed the concept of market socialism, a postcapitalist economy that retains market competition but socializes the means of production, and in some versions, extends democracy to the workplace. Some holdout for a nonmarket, participatory economy. All democratic socialists agree on the need for a democratic alternative to capitalism.»
- ↑ Guérin, Daniel (1970). Anarchism: From Theory to Practice. New York: Monthly Review Press.
- ↑ Binkley, Robert C. Realism and Nationalism 1852-1871. Read Books. էջ 118.
- ↑ «Introduction». Mutualist.org. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 17 June 2019-ին. Վերցված է 29 April 2010-ին.
- ↑ Miller, David (1987). «Mutualism». The Blackwell Encyclopedia of Political Thought. Blackwell Publishing. էջ 11.
- ↑ Tandy, Francis D. (1896). «Chapter 6». Voluntary Socialism.
- ↑ Proudhon, Pierre-Joseph (1927). Cohen, Henry (ed.). Proudhon's Solution of the Social Problem. Vanguard Press.
- ↑ Swartz, Clarence Lee. «What is Mutualism? VI. Land and Rent». Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2020-12-04-ին. Վերցված է 2014-05-05-ին.
- ↑ Crowder, George (1991). Classical Anarchism: The Political Thought of Godwin, Proudhon, Bakunin, and Kropotkin. Oxford: Clarendon Press. էջեր 85–86. ISBN 9780198277446. «The ownership [anarchists oppose] is basically that which is unearned [...] including such things as interest on loans and income from rent. This is contrasted with ownership rights in those goods either produced by the work of the owner or necessary for that work, for example his dwelling-house, land and tools. Proudhon initially refers to legitimate rights of ownership of these goods as 'possession,' and although in his latter work he calls this 'property,' the conceptual distinction remains the same.»
- ↑ Hargreaves, David H. (2019). Beyond Schooling: An Anarchist Challenge. London: Routledge. էջեր 90–91. ISBN 9780429582363. «Ironically, Proudhon did not mean literally what he said. His boldness of expression was intended for emphasis, and by 'property' he wished to be understood what he later called 'the sum of its abuses'. He was denouncing the property of the man who uses it to exploit the labour of others without any effort on his own part, property distinguished by interest and rent, by the impositions of the non-producer on the producer. Towards property regarded as 'possession' the right of a man to control his dwelling and the land and tools he needs to live, Proudhon had no hostility; indeed, he regarded it as the cornerstone of liberty, and his main criticism of the communists was that they wished to destroy it.»
- ↑ The Anarchist FAQ Editorial Collective. «Section G - Is individualist anarchism capitalistic?». An Anarchist FAQ (PDF). Արխիվացված (PDF) օրիգինալից 1 March 2021-ին. Վերցված է 5 June 2020-ին.
- ↑ The Anarchist FAQ Editorial Collective. «Replies to Some Errors and Distortions in Bryan Caplan's 'Anarchist Theory FAQ' version 5.2». An Anarchist FAQ. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 22 November 2018-ին. Վերցված է 24 August 2020-ին. «Tucker and Bakunin both shared Proudhon's opposition to private property (in the capitalist sense of the word), although Tucker confused this opposition (and possibly the casual reader) by talking about possession as 'property'»
- ↑ Various Authors. «Benjamin Tucker: Capitalist or Anarchist». An Anarchist FAQ. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից 7 January 2012-ին.
- ↑ Tucker, Benjamin. Individual Liberty. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2012-05-03-ին. Վերցված է 2016-10-28-ին. «The economic principles of Modern Socialism are a logical deduction from the principle laid down by Adam Smith in the early chapters of his "Wealth of Nations," – namely, that labor is the true measure of price...Half a century or more after Smith enunciated the principle above stated, Socialism picked it up where he had dropped it, and in following it to its logical conclusions, made it the basis of a new economic philosophy...This seems to have been done independently by three different men, of three different nationalities, in three different languages: Josiah Warren, an American; Pierre J. Proudhon, a Frenchman; Karl Marx, a German Jew...That the work of this interesting trio should have been done so nearly simultaneously would seem to indicate that Socialism was in the air, and that the time was ripe and the conditions favorable for the appearance of this new school of thought...So far as priority of time is concerned, the credit seems to belong to Warren, the American, – a fact which should be noted by the stump orators who are so fond of declaiming against Socialism as an imported article.»
- ↑ «"Anarchist Individualism as a Life and Activity" by Émile Armand». Spaz.org. 1 March 2002. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 12 June 2018-ին. Վերցված է 11 October 2013-ին.
- ↑ Armand, Émile (16 April 2020). «Anarchist Individualism and Amorous Comradeship». Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 24 November 2016-ին. Վերցված է 21 April 2020-ին.
- ↑ Igualada, Miguel Giménez. «Anarquismo» [Anarchism] (PDF) (իսպաներեն). Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից (PDF) 31 January 2017-ին. Վերցված է 28 October 2016-ին. «el capitalismo es sólo el efecto del gobierno; desaparecido el gobierno, el capitalismo cae de su pedestal vertiginosamente.... Lo que llamamos capitalismo no es otra cosa que el producto del Estado, dentro del cual lo único que se cultiva es la ganancia, bien o mal habida. Luchar, pues, contra el capitalismo es tarea inútil, porque sea Capitalismo de Estado o Capitalismo de Empresa, mientras el Gobierno exista, existirá el capital que explota. La lucha, pero de conciencias, es contra el Estado.» [capitalism is only the effect of the government; once the government is gone, capitalism falls from its pedestal vertiginously.... What we call capitalism is nothing other than the product of the State, within which the only thing that is cultivated is profit , well or ill-gotten. Fighting, then, against capitalism is a useless task, because whether it is State Capitalism or Company Capitalism, as long as the Government exists, the capital that exploits will exist. The fight, but of conscience, is against the State. ]
- ↑ Igualada, Miguel Giménez. «Anarquismo» [Anarchism] (PDF) (իսպաներեն). Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից (PDF) 31 January 2017-ին. Վերցված է 28 October 2016-ին. «¿La propiedad? ¡Bah! No es problema. Porque cuando nadie trabaje para nadie, el acaparador de la riqueza desaparece, como ha de desaparecer el gobierno cuando nadie haga caso a los que aprendieron cuatro cosas en las universidades y por ese sólo hecho pretenden gobernar a los hombres. Porque si en la tierra de los ciegos el tuerto es rey, en donde todos ven y juzgan y disciernen, el rey estorba. Y de lo que se trata es de que no haya reyes porque todos sean hombres. Las grandes empresas industriales las transformarán los hombres en grandes asociaciones donde todos trabajen y disfruten del producto de su trabajo. Y de esos tan sencillos como hermosos problemas trata el anarquismo y al que lo cumple y vive es al que se le llama anarquista...El hincapié que sin cansancio debe hacer el anarquista es el de que nadie debe explotar a nadie, ningún hombre a ningún hombre, porque esa no-explotación llevaría consigo la limitación de la propiedad a las necesidades individuales.» [Property? Bah! It's not a problem. Because when no one works for anyone, the hoarder of wealth disappears, as the government must disappear when no one pays attention to those who learned four things in the universities and for that sole reason they claim to govern men. Because if in the land of the blind the one-eyed man is king, where everyone sees and judges and discerns, the king is in the way. And what is involved is that there are no kings because they are all men. large industrial companies will be transformed by men into large associations where everyone works and enjoys the product of their work. And anarchism deals with those problems that are as simple as they are beautiful and the one who complies with them and lives is the one who is called an anarchist... The emphasis that the anarchist must tirelessly make is that no one should exploit anyone, no man to no man, because that non-exploitation would entail the limitation of property to individual needs.]
- ↑ Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty. Brooklyn, NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia.
- ↑ Carson, Kevin A. (2008). Organization Theory: A Libertarian Perspective. Charleston, SC: BookSurge.
- ↑ Carson, Kevin A. (2010). The Homebrew Industrial Revolution: A Low-Overhead Manifesto. Charleston, SC: BookSurge.
- ↑ Long, Roderick T. (2000). Reason and Value: Aristotle versus Rand. Washington, DC: Objectivist Center.
- ↑ Long, Roderick T. (2008). «An Interview With Roderick Long». Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2020-03-27-ին. Վերցված է 2014-05-05-ին.
- ↑ Johnson, Charles W. (2008). «Liberty, Equality, Solidarity: Toward a Dialectical Anarchism». In Long, Roderick T.; Machan, Tibor (eds.). Anarchism/Minarchism: Is a Government Part of a Free Country?. Aldershot: Ashgate. էջեր 155–188. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2022-06-26-ին. Վերցված է 2014-05-05-ին.
- ↑ Spangler, Brad (15 September 2006). «Market Anarchism as Stigmergic Socialism». Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից 10 May 2011-ին.
- ↑ Konkin III, Samuel Edward. The New Libertarian Manifesto (PDF). Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից (PDF) 5 June 2014-ին. Վերցված է 5 May 2014-ին.
- ↑ Richman, Sheldon (16 July 2006). «Why Left-Libertarian?». Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 3 January 2020-ին. Վերցված է 23 June 2010-ին.
- ↑ Richman, Sheldon (18 December 2009). «Workers of the World Unite for a Free Market». Freeman Online. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից 22 July 2014-ին.
- ↑ 101,0 101,1 Richman, Sheldon (3 February 2011). «Libertarian Left: Free-market anti-capitalism, the unknown ideal». The American Conservative. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից 10 June 2019-ին. Վերցված է 5 March 2012-ին.
- ↑ Sciabarra, Chris Matthew (2000). Total Freedom: Toward a Dialectical Libertarianism. University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University Press.
- ↑ Chartier, Gary (2009). Economic Justice and Natural Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
- ↑ Gillis, William (2011). «The Freed Market». In Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (eds.). Markets Not Capitalism. Brooklyn, NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia. էջեր 19–20.
- ↑ Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty. Brooklyn, NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia. էջեր 1–16.
- ↑ Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W., eds. (5 November 2011). Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty (1 ed.). Minor Compositions.
- ↑ Gary Chartier has joined Kevin Carson, Charles Johnson, and others (echoing the language of Benjamin Tucker and Thomas Hodgskin) in maintaining that, because of its heritage and its emancipatory goals and potential, radical market anarchism should be seen – by its proponents and by others – as part of the socialist tradition, and that market anarchists can and should call themselves "socialists." See Gary Chartier, "Advocates of Freed Markets Should Oppose Capitalism," "Free-Market Anti-Capitalism?" session, annual conference, Association of Private Enterprise Education (Cæsar's Palace, Las Vegas, NV, 13 April 2010); Gary Chartier, "Advocates of Freed Markets Should Embrace 'Anti-Capitalism'" Արխիվացված 2019-09-29 Wayback Machine; Gary Chartier, Socialist Ends, Market Means: Five Essays Արխիվացված 2019-03-28 Wayback Machine. Cp. Tucker, "Socialism."
- ↑ Chris Sciabarra is the only scholar associated with this school of left-libertarianism who is skeptical about anarchism; see Sciabarra's Total Freedom.
- ↑ Vallentyne, Peter; Steiner, Hillel (2000). The origins of Left Libertarianism. Palgrave Macmillan.
- ↑ Long, Roderick T. (2006). Rothbard's 'Left and Right': Forty Years Later. Rothbard Memorial Lecture, Austrian Scholars Conference. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2022-06-07-ին. Վերցված է 2016-03-18-ին.
- ↑ Related, arguably synonymous, terms include libertarianism, left-wing libertarianism, egalitarian-libertarianism, and libertarian socialism.
- Sundstrom, William A. "An Egalitarian-Libertarian Manifesto Արխիվացված 2013-10-29 Wayback Machine."
- Bookchin, Murray (1997). Biehl, Janet (ed.). The Murray Bookchin Reader. New York: Cassell. էջ 170.
- Sullivan, Mark A. (July 2003). "Why the Georgist Movement Has Not Succeeded: A Personal Response to the Question Raised by Warren J. Samuels." American Journal of Economics and Sociology. 62:3. p. 612.
- ↑ Vallentyne, Peter; Steiner, Hillel; Otsuka, Michael (2005). «Why Left-Libertarianism Is Not Incoherent, Indeterminate, or Irrelevant: A Reply to Fried» (PDF). Philosophy and Public Affairs. 33 (2): 201–215. doi:10.1111/j.1088-4963.2005.00030.x. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից (PDF) 3 November 2012-ին. Վերցված է 23 July 2013-ին.
- ↑ 113,0 113,1 113,2 Narveson, Jan; Trenchard, David (2008). «Left Libertarianism». In Hamowy, Ronald (ed.). The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE; Cato Institute. էջեր 288–89. doi:10.4135/9781412965811.n174. ISBN 978-1-4129-6580-4. LCCN 2008009151. OCLC 750831024. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 2023-01-09-ին. Վերցված է 2016-12-02-ին.
- ↑ Schnack, William (13 November 2015). «Panarchy Flourishes Under Geo-Mutualism». Center for a Stateless Society. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից 10 August 2018-ին. Վերցված է 10 August 2018-ին.
- ↑ Byas, Jason Lee (25 November 2015). «The Moral Irrelevance of Rent». Center for a Stateless Society. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 28 March 2019-ին. Վերցված է 21 March 2020-ին.
- ↑ Carson, Kevin (8 November 2015). «Are We All Mutualists?». Center for a Stateless Society. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից 28 March 2019-ին. Վերցված է 21 March 2020-ին.
- ↑ Gillis, William (29 November 2015). "The Organic Emergence of Property from Reputation" Արխիվացված 2020-03-27 Wayback Machine. Center for a Stateless Society. Retrieved 8 April 2020.
- ↑ Bylund, Per (2005). Man and Matter: A Philosophical Inquiry into the Justification of Ownership in Land from the Basis of Self-Ownership (PDF). LUP Student Papers (Master's). Lund University. Արխիվացված (PDF) օրիգինալից 6 September 2021-ին. Վերցված է 12 July 2020-ին.
- ↑ Long, Roderick T. (2006). «Land-locked: A Critique of Carson on Property Rights» (PDF). Journal of Libertarian Studies. 20 (1): 87–95. Արխիվացված (PDF) օրիգինալից 2014-07-08-ին. Վերցված է 2020-09-06-ին.
- ↑ Verhaegh, Marcus (2006). «Rothbard as a Political Philosopher» (PDF). Journal of Libertarian Studies. 20 (4): 3. Արխիվացված (PDF) օրիգինալից 2013-09-11-ին. Վերցված է 2020-09-06-ին.
- ↑ McNally, David (1993). Against the Market: Political Economy, Market Socialism and the Marxist Critique. Verso Books. ISBN 978-0-86091-606-2.
Further reading
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]- Alejandro Agafonow (2012). "The Austrian Dehomogenization Debate, or the Possibility of a Hayekian Planner," Review of Political Economy, Vol. 24, No. 02.
- Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty. Brooklyn, NY:Minor Compositions/Autonomedia
- Bertell Ollman ed. (1998). Market Socialism: the Debate Among Socialists, with other contributions by James Lawler, Hillel Ticktin and David Schewikart. Preview.
- O'Donnell, Steven (2003). Introducing Entrepreneurial Activity Into Market Socialist Models. Auckland: Auckland University Press.
- Roemer, John E. (1996). Wright, E. O. (ed.). Equal Shares: Making Market Socialism Work. Verso Books.
- Nove, Alec (1983). The Economics of Feasible Socialism. HarperCollins.
- Miller, David (1989). Market, State, and Community: Theoretical Foundations of Market Socialism. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
- Schweickart, David (2002). After Capitalism. Lanham, Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield.
- Bockman, Johanna (2011). Markets in the Name of Socialism: The Left-Wing Origins of Neoliberalism. Stanford: Stanford University Press. ISBN 978-0-8047-7566-3.