Cliometrics: Difference between revisions
Filled in 1 bare reference(s) with reFill () |
Ziggymister1 (talk | contribs) |
||
(42 intermediate revisions by 31 users not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{Short description|Application of econometrics and other formal methods to the study of history}} |
|||
'''Cliometrics''' (klīəˈmetriks{{needs IPA|date=November 2018}}), sometimes called '''new socialhistory''',<ref>{{cite journal |
|||
'''Cliometrics''' ({{IPAc-en|ˌ|k|l|aɪ|.|oʊ|ə|ˈ|m|ɛ|t|.|ɹ|ɪ|k|s}}, <small>also</small> {{IPAc-en|ˌ|k|l|iː|oʊ|ˈ|m|ɛ|t|.|ɹ|ɪ|k|s}}), sometimes called '<nowiki/>'''new economic history''''<ref>{{cite journal |
|||
| jstor =2593168 |
| jstor =2593168 |
||
| title =The New Economic History. Its Findings and Methods |
| title =The New Economic History. Its Findings and Methods |
||
| first =Robert |
| first =Robert |
||
| last =Fogel |
| last =Fogel |
||
| |
| author-link =Robert W. Fogel |
||
|date= December 1966 |
|date= December 1966 |
||
| journal =[[Economic History Review]] |volume=19 |issue=3 |pages=642–656 |
| journal =[[Economic History Review]] |volume=19 |issue=3 |pages=642–656 |
||
| quote =The 'new economic history', sometimes called economic history or cliometrics, is not often practiced in Europe. However, it is fair to say that efforts to apply statistical and mathematical models currently occupy the centre of the stage in American economic history. |
| quote =The 'new economic history', sometimes called economic history or cliometrics, is not often practiced in Europe. However, it is fair to say that efforts to apply statistical and mathematical models currently occupy the centre of the stage in American economic history. |
||
| doi=10.1111/j.1468-0289.1966.tb00994.x |
| doi=10.1111/j.1468-0289.1966.tb00994.x |
||
}}</ref> or '''econometric history''',<ref>{{cite journal |
}}</ref> or '<nowiki/>'''econometric history'<nowiki/>''',<ref>{{cite journal |
||
| jstor =202334 |
| jstor =202334 |
||
| title =Economic History and Economic Theory: The New Economic History in America |
| title =Economic History and Economic Theory: The New Economic History in America |
||
Line 18: | Line 18: | ||
| journal =[[Journal of Interdisciplinary History]] |volume=3 |issue=2 |pages=323–350 |
| journal =[[Journal of Interdisciplinary History]] |volume=3 |issue=2 |pages=323–350 |
||
| quote =Among the most recent of the changes in emphasis-today's new history-is the rise of the "new economic history" or, as it is variously called, econometric history or cliometric. |
| quote =Among the most recent of the changes in emphasis-today's new history-is the rise of the "new economic history" or, as it is variously called, econometric history or cliometric. |
||
| doi =10.2307/202334 |
|||
}}</ref> is the systematic application of economic theory, [[econometric]] techniques, and other formal or mathematical methods to the study of history (especially [[social history|social]] and [[economic history]]).<ref>{{Cite book |
}}</ref> is the systematic application of economic theory, [[econometric]] techniques, and other formal or mathematical methods to the study of history (especially [[social history|social]] and [[economic history]]).<ref>{{Cite book| url=https://www.springer.com/us/book/9783642404054| isbn=9783642404054| title=Handbook of Cliometrics| publisher=Springer| year=2016| access-date=2015-09-30| archive-date=2019-04-16| archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190416063248/https://www.springer.com/us/book/9783642404054| url-status=dead}}</ref> It is a [[Quantitative research|quantitative]] approach to economic history (as opposed to [[Qualitative research|qualitative]] or [[Ethnography|ethnographic]]).<ref name="Glaeser">[[Edward L. Glaeser]], [https://economix.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/10/27/remembering-the-father-of-transportation-economics/ "Remembering the Father of Transportation Economics"], ''The New York Times'' (Economix), October 27, 2009.</ref> |
||
| last = Goldin |
|||
| first = Claudia |
|||
⚫ | There has been a revival in 'new economic history' since the late 1990s.<ref name=":0">{{Cite web|url=http://voxeu.org/content/long-economic-and-political-shadow-history-volume-1|title=The Long Economic and Political Shadow of History, Volume 1|date=2017-01-23|website=VoxEU.org|access-date=2017-03-08|archive-date=2020-01-01|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200101063453/https://voxeu.org/content/long-economic-and-political-shadow-history-volume-1|url-status=dead}}</ref><ref name=":1">{{Cite journal|last=Abramitzky|first=Ran|date=2015 |title=Economics and the Modern Economic Historian |journal=[[Journal of Economic History]] |volume=75 |issue=4 |pages=1240–1251 |doi=10.1017/S0022050715001667 |s2cid=149483837|url=http://www.nber.org/papers/w21636.pdf}}</ref> |
||
| authorlink = Claudia Goldin |
|||
|date= Spring 1995 |
|||
| title = Cliometrics and the Nobel |
|||
| journal = The Journal of Economic Perspectives |
|||
| volume = 9 |
|||
| issue = 2 |
|||
| pages = 191–208 [p. 191] |
|||
| jstor = 2138173 |
|||
| doi=10.1257/jep.9.2.191 |
|||
⚫ | |||
[[File:Pierre Mignard 001.jpg|thumb|200px|right|[[Clio]] by [[Pierre Mignard]], oil on canvas, 1689]] |
[[File:Pierre Mignard 001.jpg|thumb|200px|right|[[Clio]] by [[Pierre Mignard]], oil on canvas, 1689]] |
||
==History |
==History== |
||
The new economic history originated in 1958 with ''The Economics of Slavery in the Antebellum South'' by American economists [[Alfred H. Conrad]] and [[John R. Meyer]] |
The new economic history originated in 1958 with ''The Economics of Slavery in the Antebellum South'' by American economists [[Alfred H. Conrad]] and [[John R. Meyer]]. The book would cause a firestorm of controversy with its claim, based on statistical data, that slavery would not have ended in the absence of the U.S. Civil War, as the practice was economically efficient and highly profitable for slaveowners.<ref name="Glaeser"/><ref>{{cite journal |title=The Economics of Slavery in the Ante Bellum South |first1=Alfred H. |last1=Conrad |first2=John R. |last2=Meyer |journal=[[Journal of Political Economy]] |volume=66 |issue=2 |year=1958 |pages=95–130 |jstor=1827270 |doi=10.1086/258020|s2cid=154825201 }}</ref> |
||
The term ''cliometrics''—which derives from [[Clio]], who was the [[muse]] of history—was originally coined by [[mathematical economist]] [[Stanley Reiter]] in 1960.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Goldin|first=Claudia|author-link=Claudia Goldin|date=Spring 1995|title=Cliometrics and the Nobel|url=http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:30703876|journal=The Journal of Economic Perspectives|volume=9|issue=2|pages=191–208 [p. 191]|doi=10.1257/jep.9.2.191|jstor=2138173|s2cid=155075681}}</ref> Cliometrics became better known when [[Douglass North]] and William Parker became the editors of the ''[[Journal of Economic History]]'' in 1960. The Cliometrics Meetings also began to be held around this time at [[Purdue University]] and are still held annually in different locations. |
|||
⚫ | North, a professor at Washington University in St. Louis, would go on to win the [[Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences]] in October 1993 along with [[Robert William Fogel]], himself often described as the father of modern econometric history and Neo-historicals.<ref name="nobelpress">The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1993, [http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1993/press.html Press Release], October 12, 2003.</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Diebolt|first1=Claude|last2=Haupert|first2=Michael|date=2017-10-28|title=A cliometric counterfactual: what if there had been neither Fogel nor North?|url=http://www.beta-umr7522.fr/productions/publications/2017/2017-04.pdf|journal=Cliometrica|language=en|volume=12|issue=3|pages=407–434|doi=10.1007/s11698-017-0167-8|s2cid=157074858|issn=1863-2505}}</ref> The two were honoured "for having renewed research in economic history;" the Academy noted that "they were pioneers in the branch of economic history that has been called the 'new economic history,' or cliometrics."<ref name="nobelpress" /> Fogel and North received the prize for turning the theoretical and statistical tools of modern economics on the historical past: on subjects ranging from slavery and railroads to ocean shipping and property rights. North was heralded as a pioneer in the "new" institutional history. In the Nobel announcement,<ref name="nobelpress" /><ref name=":2">{{Cite journal|last1=Diebolt|first1=Claude|last2=Haupert|first2=Michael|date=2017-01-01|title=A Cliometric Counterfactual: What if There Had Been Neither Fogel nor North?|url=http://econpapers.repec.org/paper/ulpsbbeta/2017-04.htm}}</ref> specific mention was made of a 1968 paper on ocean shipping, in which North showed that organizational changes played a greater role in increasing productivity than did technological change.<ref>{{cite journal|last=North|first=Douglass C.|year=1968|title=Sources of Productivity Change in Ocean Shipping, 1600-1850|journal=[[Journal of Political Economy]]|volume=76|issue=5|pages=953–970|doi=10.1086/259462|jstor=1830031|s2cid=153985679}}</ref> Fogel is especially noted for using careful empirical work to overturn [[conventional wisdom]]. |
||
With that being said, the new economic history revolution is thought to have begun in the mid-1960s, where areas of key interest included transportation history,<ref name="Fogel64">{{cite book|last=Fogel|first=R.|url=https://archive.org/details/railroadsamerica00foge|title=Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History|publisher=The Johns Hopkins University Press|year=1964|isbn=978-0-8018-0201-0|edition=1st|url-access=registration}}</ref> slavery,<ref name="Glaeser" /> and agriculture. The discipline was resisted as many incumbent economic historians were either historians or economists who had very little connection to economic modeling or statistical techniques.<ref>{{cite journal |
|||
| last = Goldin |
| last = Goldin |
||
| first = Claudia |
| first = Claudia |
||
| |
| author-link = Claudia Goldin |
||
|date= Spring 1995 |
|date= Spring 1995 |
||
| title = Cliometrics and the Nobel |
| title = Cliometrics and the Nobel |
||
Line 46: | Line 43: | ||
| jstor = 2138173 |
| jstor = 2138173 |
||
| doi=10.1257/jep.9.2.191 |
| doi=10.1257/jep.9.2.191 |
||
| s2cid = 155075681 |
|||
}}</ref> Areas of key interest included transportation history,<ref name="Fogel64">{{cite book |last=Fogel |first=R. |title=Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History |year=1964 |publisher=The Johns Hopkins University Press |edition=1st |isbn=978-0-8018-0201-0 }}</ref> slavery,<ref name="Glaeser"/> and agriculture. Cliometrics became better known when [[Douglass North]] and William Parker became the editors of the ''[[Journal of Economic History]]'' in 1960. The Cliometrics Meetings began to be held around this time at [[Purdue University]] and are still held annually in different locations. Today, cliometric approaches are standard in several journals, including the ''[[Journal of Economic History]]'', ''[[Explorations in Economic History]]'', the ''[[European Review of Economic History]]'', and ''[[Cliometrica]]''. |
|||
| url = http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:30703876 |
|||
}}</ref> According to cliometric economist [[Claudia Goldin]], the success of the cliometric revolution had as an unintended consequence the disappearance of economic historians from history departments. As economic historians started using the same tools as economists, they started to seem more like other economists. In Goldin's words, "the new economic historians extinguished the other side."<ref>{{cite journal|last=Goldin|first=Claudia|author-link=Claudia Goldin|date=Spring 1995|title=Cliometrics and the Nobel|url=http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:30703876|journal=The Journal of Economic Perspectives|volume=9|issue=2|pages=191–208 [p. 206]|doi=10.1257/jep.9.2.191|jstor=2138173|s2cid=155075681}}</ref> The other side nearly disappeared altogether, with only a few remaining in history departments and business schools. However, some new economic historians did, in fact, begin research around this time, among them were Kemmerer and [[Larry Neal]] (a student of [[Albert Fishlow]], a leader of the cliometric revolution) from Illinois, Paul Uselding from [[Johns Hopkins University|Johns Hopkins]], [[Jeremy Atack]] from Indiana, and [[Thomas Ulen]] from Stanford. |
|||
Cliometrics was introduced in the 1970s to Germany by [[Richard H. Tilly]], who had been and educated in the US.<ref name="autogenerated1">{{cite web|title=Verleihung des Helmut-Schmidt-Preises 2009 an Richard Hugh Tilly|url=http://www.ghi-dc.org/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=1015:helmut-schmidt-prize-lecture-2009&catid=97:lectures-2009&Itemid=908#pics|url-status=dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20131029193517/http://www.ghi-dc.org/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=1015:helmut-schmidt-prize-lecture-2009&catid=97:lectures-2009&Itemid=908#pics#pics|archive-date=2013-10-29|access-date=2013-06-22}}</ref> [[The Cliometric Society]], a group to encourage and further the study of cliometrics, was founded in 1983. |
|||
According to cliometric economist [[Claudia Goldin]], the success of the cliometric revolution had as an unintended consequence the disappearance of economic historians from history departments. As economic historians started using the same tools as economists, they started to seem more like other economists. In Goldin's words, "the new economic historians extinguished the other side".<ref>{{cite journal |
|||
| last = Goldin |
|||
| first = Claudia |
|||
| authorlink = Claudia Goldin |
|||
|date= Spring 1995 |
|||
| title = Cliometrics and the Nobel |
|||
| journal = The Journal of Economic Perspectives |
|||
| volume = 9 |
|||
| issue = 2 |
|||
| pages = 191–208 [p. 206] |
|||
| jstor = 2138173 |
|||
| doi=10.1257/jep.9.2.191 |
|||
}}</ref> The other side nearly disappeared altogether, with only a few remaining in history departments and business schools. However, some new economic historians did, in fact, begin research around this time, among them were Kemmerer and Larry Neal (a student of [[Albert Fishlow]], a leader of the cliometric revolution) from Illinois, Paul Uselding from [[Johns Hopkins University|Johns Hopkins]], Jeremy Atack from Indiana, and Thomas Ulen from Stanford. |
|||
A group to encourage and further the study of cliometrics, [[The Cliometric Society]], was founded in 1983. |
|||
Cliometrics was introduced to Germany by American-born and -educated [[Richard H. Tilly]] in the 1970s.<ref name=autogenerated1>{{cite web|url=http://www.ghi-dc.org/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=1015:helmut-schmidt-prize-lecture-2009&catid=97:lectures-2009&Itemid=908#pics|title=Verleihung des Helmut-Schmidt-Preises 2009 an Richard Hugh Tilly|publisher=}}</ref> |
|||
⚫ | There has been a revival in 'new economic history' since the late 1990s.<ref name=":0" /><ref name=":1" /> The number of papers on economic history published in the top economics journals has increased in the last decades, comprising 6.6% of articles in the [[The American Economic Review|American Economic Review]] and 10.8% of articles in the [[Quarterly Journal of Economics]] for the period 2004-2014.<ref name=":1" /> |
||
==Nobel Prize in Economics== |
|||
In October 1993, the Swedish National Bank awarded the [[Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences]] to [[Robert William Fogel]] and [[Douglass Cecil North]] "for having renewed research in economic history". The Academy noted that "they were pioneers in the branch of economic history that has been called the 'new economic history,' or cliometrics".<ref name="nobelpress">The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1993, [http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1993/press.html Press Release], October 12, 2003.</ref> Fogel and North received the prize for turning the theoretical and statistical tools of modern economics on the historical past: on subjects ranging from slavery and railroads to ocean shipping and property rights. |
|||
⚫ | There has been a revival in 'new economic history' since the late 1990s.<ref name=":0" /><ref name=":1" /> The number of papers on economic history published in the top economics journals has increased in the last decades, comprising 6.6% of articles in the [[The American Economic Review|''American Economic Review'']] and 10.8% of articles in the ''[[Quarterly Journal of Economics]]'' for the period 2004-2014.<ref name=":1" /> Today, cliometric approaches are standard in several journals, including the ''[[Journal of Economic History]]'', ''[[Explorations in Economic History]]'', the ''[[European Review of Economic History]]'', and ''[[Cliometrica]]''. |
||
⚫ | Fogel |
||
==Critics== |
==Critics== |
||
Cliometrics has had sharp critics. Boldizzoni summarized a common critique by arguing that cliometrics is based on the false assumption that the laws of neo-classical economics always apply to human activity. |
Cliometrics has had sharp critics. [[Francesco Boldizzoni]] summarized a common critique by arguing that cliometrics is based on the false assumption that the laws of neo-classical economics always apply to human activity. The considers that those laws are based on [[rational choice]] and maximization, as they operate in well-developed markets, and do not apply to economies other than those of the capitalist West in the modern era. Instead, Boldizzoni argues that the workings of economies are determined by social, political, and cultural conditions specific to each society and time period.<ref>{{cite book |first=Francesco |last=Boldizzoni |title=The Poverty of Clio: Resurrecting Economic History |publisher=Princeton University Press |year=2011 |isbn=9780691144009 }}</ref> |
||
On the other hand, Diebolt<ref>{{cite journal |
On the other hand, Claude Diebolt (2016) argued that cliometrics is mature and well accepted by scholars as an "indispensable tool" in economic history.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Diebolt|first1=Claude|year=2016|title=Cliometrica after 10 years: definition and principles of cliometric research|journal=Cliometrica|volume=10|pages=1–4|doi=10.1007/s11698-015-0136-z|doi-access=free}}</ref> He believes that most scholars agree that economic theory, combined with new data as well as historical and statistical methods are necessary to formulate problems precisely, to draw conclusions from postulates and to gain insight into complex processes to close the gap between ''Geisteswissenschaften'' and ''Naturwissenschaften'': to move from the historical ''verstehen'' or understanding side to the economic ''erklären'' or explaining side or, much better, mixing both approaches for the achievement of a unified approach of the social sciences. At the applied level, cliometrics is accepted to measure variables and estimate parameters.<ref>{{cite journal |first=Claude |last=Diebolt |title=Where Are We Now in Cliometrics? Kliometrie: wo stehen wir heute? |journal=Historical Social Research |year=2012 |volume=37 |issue=4 |pages=309–326 }}</ref> |
||
A criticism |
A criticism by [[Joseph T. Salerno]], based on the perspective of the [[Austrian School]] of economics, especially that of [[Ludwig von Mises]], can be found in his Introduction to [[Murray N. Rothbard]]'s ''[[A History of Money and Banking in the United States]]''.<ref>{{cite book |
||
| first =Murray |
| first =Murray |
||
| last =Rothbard |
| last =Rothbard |
||
Line 88: | Line 66: | ||
==Distinguishing cliometrics and cliodynamics== |
==Distinguishing cliometrics and cliodynamics== |
||
Cliometrics and [[cliodynamics]] share the scientific ambition of using quantitative tools and historical data to test general historical principles. Both fields endeavor to gather large amounts of historical data across big samples. However, the two fields also differ in several |
Cliometrics and [[cliodynamics]] share the scientific ambition of using quantitative tools and historical data to test general historical principles. Both fields endeavor to gather large amounts of historical data across big samples. However, the two fields also differ in several ways. |
||
Cliodynamics maintains a close relationship with the natural sciences, often employing dominant methods from the natural sciences such as differential-equation models, power-law relations, and agent-based models. [[Evolutionary game theory]] and social network analysis are also frequently employed by cliodynamicists, but less often by cliometricians. Cliodynamicists also tend to include factors associated with ecological context and biological determinants in their models.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Mejía|first=Javier|date=2015|title= The Evolution of Economic History since 1950: From Cliometrics to Cliodynamics|ssrn= 2708321|journal=Tiempo & Economia|volume=2|issue=2|pages=79–103|doi=10.21789/24222704.1061|doi-access=free|hdl=20.500.12010/733|hdl-access=free}}</ref> |
|||
⚫ | |||
⚫ | |||
* [[Critical juncture theory]] |
|||
* [[Economic history]] |
* [[Economic history]] |
||
* [[Quantitative history]] |
* [[Quantitative history]] |
||
* [[Cliodynamics]] |
* [[Cliodynamics]] |
||
* [[Structural-demographic theory]] |
|||
*[[Anthropometric history |
* [[Anthropometric history]] |
||
==References== |
==References== |
||
{{ |
{{Reflist}} |
||
==Further reading== |
==Further reading== |
||
{{Library resources box}} |
|||
*{{cite book |last=Boldizzoni |first=Francesco |title=The Poverty of Clio: Resurrecting Economic History |publisher=Princeton University Press |year=2011 }} Excerpt in [http://www.themontrealreview.com/2009/The-poverty-of-Clio-Boldizzoni.php ''The Montreal Review''] |
*{{cite book |last=Boldizzoni |first=Francesco |title=The Poverty of Clio: Resurrecting Economic History |publisher=Princeton University Press |year=2011 }} Excerpt in [http://www.themontrealreview.com/2009/The-poverty-of-Clio-Boldizzoni.php ''The Montreal Review''] |
||
*[https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11698-019-00186-x Martina Cioni, Giovanni Federico, Michelangelo Vasta. 2019. "The long-term evolution of economic history: evidence from the top five field journals (1927–2017)." ''Cliometrica''] |
|||
*Diebolt, C.; Haupert, M. Eds. (2019). ''Handbook of Cliometrics'', 2nd Edition, Springer Nature, 1768 pages. |
|||
*{{cite book |last=Drukker |first=J. W. |title=The Revolution that Bit its Own Tail: How Economic History Changed our Ideas on Economic Growth |location=Amsterdam |year=2006 }} |
*{{cite book |last=Drukker |first=J. W. |title=The Revolution that Bit its Own Tail: How Economic History Changed our Ideas on Economic Growth |location=Amsterdam |year=2006 }} |
||
*{{cite book |last=Fogel |first=R. |title=Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History |year=1964 }} |
*{{cite book |last=Fogel |first=R. |title=Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History |year=1964 }} |
||
*{{cite book | |
*{{cite book |last1=Fogel |first1=Robert William |last2=Engerman |first2=Stanley L. |title=Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery |edition=Reissue |location=New York |publisher=W. W. Norton and Company |year=1995 |isbn=978-0-393-31218-8 |title-link=Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery }} |
||
*{{cite book |editor-last=Lyons |editor-first=John S. |editor2-first=Louis P. |editor2-last=Cain |editor3-first=Samuel H. |editor3-last=Williamson |title=Reflections on the Cliometrics Revolution: Conversations with Economic Historians |publisher=Routledge |year=2008 |isbn=978-0-415-70091-7 }} Reprinted interviews from the ''Newsletter of the Cliometric Society'' ([https://books.google. |
*{{cite book |editor-last=Lyons |editor-first=John S. |editor2-first=Louis P. |editor2-last=Cain |editor3-first=Samuel H. |editor3-last=Williamson |title=Reflections on the Cliometrics Revolution: Conversations with Economic Historians |publisher=Routledge |year=2008 |isbn=978-0-415-70091-7 }} Reprinted interviews from the ''Newsletter of the Cliometric Society'' ([https://books.google.com/books?id=0w-UAgAAQBAJ&pg=PAi excerpts]) |
||
* Robert A. Margo ( |
* Robert A. Margo (2018): "The Integration of Economic History into Economics", [https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11698-018-0170-8 ''Cliometrica''], NBER Working Paper No. 23538 {{doi|10.3386/w23538}} |
||
*{{cite journal |last=North |first=Douglas |title=The State of Economic History |journal=[[American Economic Review]] |volume=55 |issue=1–2 |year=1965 |pages=86–91 |jstor=1816246 }} |
*{{cite journal |last=North |first=Douglas |title=The State of Economic History |journal=[[American Economic Review]] |volume=55 |issue=1–2 |year=1965 |pages=86–91 |jstor=1816246 }} |
||
*{{cite book | |
*{{cite book |last1=North |first1=Douglas |last2=Thomas |first2=Robert |title=The Rise of the Western World: a New Economic History |publisher=Cambridge University Press |year=1973 }} |
||
==External links== |
==External links== |
||
* [http://eh.net/clio/ The Cliometric Society] |
* [http://eh.net/clio/ The Cliometric Society] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080610102257/http://eh.net/Clio/ |date=2008-06-10 }} |
||
* [https://archive. |
* [https://archive.today/20121224040050/http://www.cliogroup.org.uk/index.htm LSE Cliometrics Group] (archived 24 December 2012) |
||
* [http://www.cliometrie.org/ Association Française de Cliométrie] |
* [http://www.cliometrie.org/ Association Française de Cliométrie] |
||
{{economics}} |
{{economics}} |
||
{{Authority control}} |
|||
[[Category:Economic history studies]] |
[[Category:Economic history studies]] |
||
⚫ | |||
[[Category:Econometric modeling]] |
[[Category:Econometric modeling]] |
||
⚫ |
Revision as of 18:01, 3 April 2024
Cliometrics (/ˌklaɪ.oʊəˈmɛt.rɪks/, also /ˌkliːoʊˈmɛt.rɪks/), sometimes called 'new economic history'[1] or 'econometric history',[2] is the systematic application of economic theory, econometric techniques, and other formal or mathematical methods to the study of history (especially social and economic history).[3] It is a quantitative approach to economic history (as opposed to qualitative or ethnographic).[4]
There has been a revival in 'new economic history' since the late 1990s.[5][6]
History
The new economic history originated in 1958 with The Economics of Slavery in the Antebellum South by American economists Alfred H. Conrad and John R. Meyer. The book would cause a firestorm of controversy with its claim, based on statistical data, that slavery would not have ended in the absence of the U.S. Civil War, as the practice was economically efficient and highly profitable for slaveowners.[4][7]
The term cliometrics—which derives from Clio, who was the muse of history—was originally coined by mathematical economist Stanley Reiter in 1960.[8] Cliometrics became better known when Douglass North and William Parker became the editors of the Journal of Economic History in 1960. The Cliometrics Meetings also began to be held around this time at Purdue University and are still held annually in different locations.
North, a professor at Washington University in St. Louis, would go on to win the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in October 1993 along with Robert William Fogel, himself often described as the father of modern econometric history and Neo-historicals.[9][10] The two were honoured "for having renewed research in economic history;" the Academy noted that "they were pioneers in the branch of economic history that has been called the 'new economic history,' or cliometrics."[9] Fogel and North received the prize for turning the theoretical and statistical tools of modern economics on the historical past: on subjects ranging from slavery and railroads to ocean shipping and property rights. North was heralded as a pioneer in the "new" institutional history. In the Nobel announcement,[9][11] specific mention was made of a 1968 paper on ocean shipping, in which North showed that organizational changes played a greater role in increasing productivity than did technological change.[12] Fogel is especially noted for using careful empirical work to overturn conventional wisdom.
With that being said, the new economic history revolution is thought to have begun in the mid-1960s, where areas of key interest included transportation history,[13] slavery,[4] and agriculture. The discipline was resisted as many incumbent economic historians were either historians or economists who had very little connection to economic modeling or statistical techniques.[14] According to cliometric economist Claudia Goldin, the success of the cliometric revolution had as an unintended consequence the disappearance of economic historians from history departments. As economic historians started using the same tools as economists, they started to seem more like other economists. In Goldin's words, "the new economic historians extinguished the other side."[15] The other side nearly disappeared altogether, with only a few remaining in history departments and business schools. However, some new economic historians did, in fact, begin research around this time, among them were Kemmerer and Larry Neal (a student of Albert Fishlow, a leader of the cliometric revolution) from Illinois, Paul Uselding from Johns Hopkins, Jeremy Atack from Indiana, and Thomas Ulen from Stanford.
Cliometrics was introduced in the 1970s to Germany by Richard H. Tilly, who had been and educated in the US.[16] The Cliometric Society, a group to encourage and further the study of cliometrics, was founded in 1983.
There has been a revival in 'new economic history' since the late 1990s.[5][6] The number of papers on economic history published in the top economics journals has increased in the last decades, comprising 6.6% of articles in the American Economic Review and 10.8% of articles in the Quarterly Journal of Economics for the period 2004-2014.[6] Today, cliometric approaches are standard in several journals, including the Journal of Economic History, Explorations in Economic History, the European Review of Economic History, and Cliometrica.
Critics
Cliometrics has had sharp critics. Francesco Boldizzoni summarized a common critique by arguing that cliometrics is based on the false assumption that the laws of neo-classical economics always apply to human activity. The considers that those laws are based on rational choice and maximization, as they operate in well-developed markets, and do not apply to economies other than those of the capitalist West in the modern era. Instead, Boldizzoni argues that the workings of economies are determined by social, political, and cultural conditions specific to each society and time period.[17]
On the other hand, Claude Diebolt (2016) argued that cliometrics is mature and well accepted by scholars as an "indispensable tool" in economic history.[18] He believes that most scholars agree that economic theory, combined with new data as well as historical and statistical methods are necessary to formulate problems precisely, to draw conclusions from postulates and to gain insight into complex processes to close the gap between Geisteswissenschaften and Naturwissenschaften: to move from the historical verstehen or understanding side to the economic erklären or explaining side or, much better, mixing both approaches for the achievement of a unified approach of the social sciences. At the applied level, cliometrics is accepted to measure variables and estimate parameters.[19]
A criticism by Joseph T. Salerno, based on the perspective of the Austrian School of economics, especially that of Ludwig von Mises, can be found in his Introduction to Murray N. Rothbard's A History of Money and Banking in the United States.[20]
Distinguishing cliometrics and cliodynamics
Cliometrics and cliodynamics share the scientific ambition of using quantitative tools and historical data to test general historical principles. Both fields endeavor to gather large amounts of historical data across big samples. However, the two fields also differ in several ways.
Cliodynamics maintains a close relationship with the natural sciences, often employing dominant methods from the natural sciences such as differential-equation models, power-law relations, and agent-based models. Evolutionary game theory and social network analysis are also frequently employed by cliodynamicists, but less often by cliometricians. Cliodynamicists also tend to include factors associated with ecological context and biological determinants in their models.[21]
See also
- Critical juncture theory
- Economic history
- Quantitative history
- Cliodynamics
- Structural-demographic theory
- Anthropometric history
References
- ^ Fogel, Robert (December 1966). "The New Economic History. Its Findings and Methods". Economic History Review. 19 (3): 642–656. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0289.1966.tb00994.x. JSTOR 2593168.
The 'new economic history', sometimes called economic history or cliometrics, is not often practiced in Europe. However, it is fair to say that efforts to apply statistical and mathematical models currently occupy the centre of the stage in American economic history.
- ^ Woodman, Harold (1972). "Economic History and Economic Theory: The New Economic History in America". Journal of Interdisciplinary History. 3 (2): 323–350. doi:10.2307/202334. JSTOR 202334.
Among the most recent of the changes in emphasis-today's new history-is the rise of the "new economic history" or, as it is variously called, econometric history or cliometric.
- ^ Handbook of Cliometrics. Springer. 2016. ISBN 9783642404054. Archived from the original on 2019-04-16. Retrieved 2015-09-30.
- ^ a b c Edward L. Glaeser, "Remembering the Father of Transportation Economics", The New York Times (Economix), October 27, 2009.
- ^ a b "The Long Economic and Political Shadow of History, Volume 1". VoxEU.org. 2017-01-23. Archived from the original on 2020-01-01. Retrieved 2017-03-08.
- ^ a b c Abramitzky, Ran (2015). "Economics and the Modern Economic Historian" (PDF). Journal of Economic History. 75 (4): 1240–1251. doi:10.1017/S0022050715001667. S2CID 149483837.
- ^ Conrad, Alfred H.; Meyer, John R. (1958). "The Economics of Slavery in the Ante Bellum South". Journal of Political Economy. 66 (2): 95–130. doi:10.1086/258020. JSTOR 1827270. S2CID 154825201.
- ^ Goldin, Claudia (Spring 1995). "Cliometrics and the Nobel". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 9 (2): 191–208 [p. 191]. doi:10.1257/jep.9.2.191. JSTOR 2138173. S2CID 155075681.
- ^ a b c The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1993, Press Release, October 12, 2003.
- ^ Diebolt, Claude; Haupert, Michael (2017-10-28). "A cliometric counterfactual: what if there had been neither Fogel nor North?" (PDF). Cliometrica. 12 (3): 407–434. doi:10.1007/s11698-017-0167-8. ISSN 1863-2505. S2CID 157074858.
- ^ Diebolt, Claude; Haupert, Michael (2017-01-01). "A Cliometric Counterfactual: What if There Had Been Neither Fogel nor North?".
{{cite journal}}
: Cite journal requires|journal=
(help) - ^ North, Douglass C. (1968). "Sources of Productivity Change in Ocean Shipping, 1600-1850". Journal of Political Economy. 76 (5): 953–970. doi:10.1086/259462. JSTOR 1830031. S2CID 153985679.
- ^ Fogel, R. (1964). Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History (1st ed.). The Johns Hopkins University Press. ISBN 978-0-8018-0201-0.
- ^ Goldin, Claudia (Spring 1995). "Cliometrics and the Nobel". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 9 (2): 191–208 [p. 194]. doi:10.1257/jep.9.2.191. JSTOR 2138173. S2CID 155075681.
- ^ Goldin, Claudia (Spring 1995). "Cliometrics and the Nobel". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 9 (2): 191–208 [p. 206]. doi:10.1257/jep.9.2.191. JSTOR 2138173. S2CID 155075681.
- ^ "Verleihung des Helmut-Schmidt-Preises 2009 an Richard Hugh Tilly". Archived from the original on 2013-10-29. Retrieved 2013-06-22.
- ^ Boldizzoni, Francesco (2011). The Poverty of Clio: Resurrecting Economic History. Princeton University Press. ISBN 9780691144009.
- ^ Diebolt, Claude (2016). "Cliometrica after 10 years: definition and principles of cliometric research". Cliometrica. 10: 1–4. doi:10.1007/s11698-015-0136-z.
- ^ Diebolt, Claude (2012). "Where Are We Now in Cliometrics? Kliometrie: wo stehen wir heute?". Historical Social Research. 37 (4): 309–326.
- ^ Rothbard, Murray (2002). A History of Money and Banking in the United States: The Colonial Era to World War II. Ludwig von Mises Institute. ISBN 978-0945466338.
- ^ Mejía, Javier (2015). "The Evolution of Economic History since 1950: From Cliometrics to Cliodynamics". Tiempo & Economia. 2 (2): 79–103. doi:10.21789/24222704.1061. hdl:20.500.12010/733. SSRN 2708321.
Further reading
- Boldizzoni, Francesco (2011). The Poverty of Clio: Resurrecting Economic History. Princeton University Press. Excerpt in The Montreal Review
- Martina Cioni, Giovanni Federico, Michelangelo Vasta. 2019. "The long-term evolution of economic history: evidence from the top five field journals (1927–2017)." Cliometrica
- Diebolt, C.; Haupert, M. Eds. (2019). Handbook of Cliometrics, 2nd Edition, Springer Nature, 1768 pages.
- Drukker, J. W. (2006). The Revolution that Bit its Own Tail: How Economic History Changed our Ideas on Economic Growth. Amsterdam.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link) - Fogel, R. (1964). Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History.
- Fogel, Robert William; Engerman, Stanley L. (1995). Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery (Reissue ed.). New York: W. W. Norton and Company. ISBN 978-0-393-31218-8.
- Lyons, John S.; Cain, Louis P.; Williamson, Samuel H., eds. (2008). Reflections on the Cliometrics Revolution: Conversations with Economic Historians. Routledge. ISBN 978-0-415-70091-7. Reprinted interviews from the Newsletter of the Cliometric Society (excerpts)
- Robert A. Margo (2018): "The Integration of Economic History into Economics", Cliometrica, NBER Working Paper No. 23538 doi:10.3386/w23538
- North, Douglas (1965). "The State of Economic History". American Economic Review. 55 (1–2): 86–91. JSTOR 1816246.
- North, Douglas; Thomas, Robert (1973). The Rise of the Western World: a New Economic History. Cambridge University Press.
External links
- The Cliometric Society Archived 2008-06-10 at the Wayback Machine
- LSE Cliometrics Group (archived 24 December 2012)
- Association Française de Cliométrie