Jump to content

Chartalism: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
style consistency
m Reverted edit by Materialscientist (talk) to last version by 156.10.31.102
 
(29 intermediate revisions by 26 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{short description|Heterodox theory of money}}
In [[macroeconomics]], '''chartalism''' is a theory of [[money]] that argues that money originated with states' attempts to direct economic activity rather than as a spontaneous solution to the problems with [[barter]] or as a means with which to tokenize debt,<ref>{{cite book|last1=Graeber|first1=David|title=Debt: The First 5000 Years|date=12 July 2011|isbn=1-933633-86-7}}</ref> and that [[fiat currency]] has value in exchange because of sovereign power to levy [[taxes]] on economic activity payable in the currency they issue.
{{distinguish|Chartism}}
{{Macroeconomics sidebar}}
{{Capitalism sidebar}}
In [[macroeconomics]], '''chartalism''' is a [[Heterodox economics|heterodox]] theory of [[money]] that argues that money originated historically with states' attempts to direct economic activity rather than as a spontaneous solution to the problems with [[barter]] or as a means with which to tokenize debt,<ref>{{cite book|last1=Graeber|first1=David|title=Debt: The First 5000 Years|date=12 July 2011|isbn=978-1-933633-86-2|url-access=registration|url=https://archive.org/details/debtfirst5000yea00grae}}</ref> and that [[fiat currency]] has value in exchange because of sovereign power to levy [[taxes]] on economic activity payable in the currency they issue.


==Background==
==Background==
[[Georg Friedrich Knapp]], a German [[economist]], coined the term "chartalism" in his ''State Theory of Money'', which was published in German in 1905 and translated into English in 1924. The name derives from the [[Latin language|Latin]] ''[[wikt:charta#Latin|charta]]'', in the sense of a token or ticket.<ref name="George Friedrich Knapp 1924 32">{{Citation|title=The State Theory of Money|author=Knapp, George Friedrich|year=1924|publisher=Macmillan and Company|pages=32}}</ref> Knapp argued that "money is a creature of law" rather than a [[commodity money|commodity]].<ref name="George Friedrich Knapp 1924">{{Citation|title=The State Theory of Money|author=Knapp, George Friedrich|year=1924|publisher=Macmillan and Company}}</ref> Knapp contrasted his state theory of money with "[[metallism]]", as embodied at the time in the [[Gold Standard]], where the value of a unit of currency depended on the quantity of precious metal it contained or could be exchanged for. He argued the state could create pure paper money and make it exchangeable by recognising it as [[legal tender]], with the criterion for the money of a state being "that which is accepted at the public pay offices".<ref name="George Friedrich Knapp 1924" />
[[Georg Friedrich Knapp]], a German [[economist]], invented the term "chartalism" in his ''State Theory of Money'', which was published in German in 1905 and translated into English in 1924. The name derives from the [[Latin language|Latin]] ''[[wikt:charta#Latin|charta]]'', in the sense of a token or ticket.<ref name="George Friedrich Knapp 1924 32">{{Citation|title=The State Theory of Money|author=Knapp, George Friedrich|year=1924|publisher=Macmillan and Company|pages=32}}</ref> Knapp argued that "money is a creature of law" rather than a [[commodity money|commodity]].<ref name="George Friedrich Knapp 1924">{{Citation|title=The State Theory of Money|author=Knapp, George Friedrich|year=1924|publisher=Macmillan and Company}}</ref> Knapp contrasted his state theory of money with "[[metallism]]", as embodied at the time in the [[gold standard]], where the value of a unit of currency depended on the quantity of precious metal it contained or could be exchanged for. He argued the state could create pure paper money and make it exchangeable by recognising it as [[legal tender]], with the criterion for the money of a state being "that which is accepted at the public pay offices".<ref name="George Friedrich Knapp 1924" />


When Knapp was writing, the prevailing view of money was that it had evolved from systems of [[barter]] to become a [[medium of exchange]] because it represented a durable [[commodity money|commodity]] which had some [[use value]]. However, as modern chartalist economists such as [[Randall Wray]] and Mathew Forstater have pointed out, chartalist insights into tax-driven paper money can be found in the earlier writings of many classical economists,<ref name="wray2000">{{Citation |title=The Neo-Chartalist Approach to Money |last=Wray |first=L. Randall |issue=Working Paper No. 10 |year=2000 |url=http://www.cfeps.org/pubs/wp/wp10.html |publisher=[[University of Missouri–Kansas City|UMKC]] Center for Full Employment and Price Stability |access-date=2019-08-27 |archive-date=2019-10-20 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191020012347/http://www.cfeps.org/pubs/wp/wp10.html |url-status=dead }}</ref><ref name=forstater>{{citation | title=Tax-Driven Money: Additional Evidence from the History of Thought, Economic History, and Economic Policy | author=Forstater, Mathew | year=2004 | url=http://www.cfeps.org/pubs/wp-pdf/WP35-Forstater.pdf | access-date=2014-07-28 | archive-date=2020-04-20 | archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200420071718/http://www.cfeps.org/pubs/wp-pdf/WP35-Forstater.pdf | url-status=dead }}</ref> for instance [[Adam Smith]], who observed in ''[[The Wealth of Nations]]'':
Constantina Katsari has argued that principles from both metallism and chartalism were reflected in the monetary system introduced by [[Augustus]], which was used in the eastern provinces of the [[Roman Empire]], from the early 1st century to the late 3rd century AD.<ref name = "CvM">

{{quotation|text=A prince, who should enact that a certain proportion of his taxes should be paid in a paper money of a certain kind, might thereby give a certain value to this paper money; even though the term of its final discharge and redemption should depend altogether on the will of the prince.|author=Adam Smith|source=An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations}}

Forstater also finds support for the concept of tax-driven money, under certain institutional conditions, in the work of [[Jean-Baptiste Say]], [[John Stuart Mill]], [[Karl Marx]] and [[William Stanley Jevons]].<ref name=forstater />

[[Alfred Mitchell-Innes]], writing in 1914, argued that money existed not as a [[medium of exchange]] but as a [[standard of deferred payment]], with government money being debt the government could reclaim by taxation.<ref name="Innes">{{cite journal | author=Mitchell-Innes, Alfred |title=The Credit Theory of Money |journal= The Banking Law Journal | year=1914 |volume=31 |url=https://www.community-exchange.org/docs/The%20Credit%20Theoriy%20of%20Money.htm}}</ref> Innes argued:
{{Quotation|text=Whenever a tax is imposed, each taxpayer becomes responsible for the redemption of a small part of the debt which the government has contracted by its issues of money, whether coins, certificates, notes, drafts on the treasury, or by whatever name this money is called. He has to acquire his portion of the debt from some holder of a coin or certificate or other form of government money, and present it to the Treasury in liquidation of his legal debt. He has to redeem or cancel that portion of the debt...The redemption of government debt by taxation is the basic law of coinage and of any issue of government ‘money’ in whatever form.|author=Alfred Mitchell-Innes|title=The Credit Theory of Money|source=The Banking Law Journal}}

Knapp and "Chartalism" were referenced by [[John Maynard Keynes]] in the opening pages of his 1930 ''[[A Treatise on Money|Treatise on Money]]'' <ref>Keynes, John Maynard: ''A Treatise on Money'', 1930, pp. 4, 6</ref> and appear to have influenced [[Keynesian]] ideas on the role of the state in the economy.<ref name="wray2000"/> By 1947, when [[Abba Lerner]] wrote his article "Money as a Creature of the State", economists had largely abandoned the idea that the value of money was closely linked to gold.<ref name=Lerner /> Lerner argued that responsibility for avoiding inflation and depressions lay with the state because of its ability to create or tax away money.<ref name=Lerner>{{cite journal| last=Lerner | first=Abba P. | journal=The American Economic Review | title=Money as a Creature of the State | volume=37 | number=2 |date=May 1947}}</ref>

Historian Constantina Katsari sees principles from both metallism and chartalism reflected in the monetary system introduced by [[Augustus]] to the eastern provinces of the [[Roman Empire]], from the early 1st century to the late 3rd century AD.<ref name = "CvM">
{{cite book
{{cite book
|editor = Stephanie A. Bell and Edward J. Nell
|editor = Stephanie A. Bell and Edward J. Nell
Line 17: Line 32:
|chapter= Chpt. 7
|chapter= Chpt. 7
|year=2011
|year=2011
|isbn=0521769469
|isbn=978-0521769464
|publisher= [[Cambridge University Press]]
|publisher= [[Cambridge University Press]]
}}</ref>
}}</ref>

When Knapp was writing, the prevailing view of money was that it had evolved from systems of [[barter]] to become a [[medium of exchange]] because it represented a durable [[commodity money|commodity]] which had some [[use value]]. However, as modern chartalist economists such as Randall Wray and Mathew Forstater have pointed out, chartalist insights into tax-driven paper money can be found in the earlier writings of many classical economists,<ref name="wray2000" /><ref name=forstater>{{citation | title=Tax-Driven Money: Additional Evidence from the History of Thought, Economic History, and Economic Policy | author=Forstater, Mathew |year=2004 |url=http://www.cfeps.org/pubs/wp-pdf/WP35-Forstater.pdf}}</ref>
for instance [[Adam Smith]], who observed in ''[[The Wealth of Nations]]'':
{{quotation | A prince, who should enact that a certain proportion of his taxes should be paid in a paper money of a certain kind, might thereby give a certain value to this paper money; even though the term of its final discharge and redemption should depend altogether on the will of the prince |Adam Smith|An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations | }}
Forstater also finds support for the concept of tax-driven money, under certain institutional conditions, in the work of [[Jean-Baptiste Say]], [[J.S. Mill]], [[Karl Marx]] and [[William Stanley Jevons]].<ref name=forstater />

[[Alfred Mitchell-Innes]], writing in 1914, argued that money existed not as a [[medium of exchange]] but as a [[standard of deferred payment]], with government money being debt the government could reclaim by taxation.<ref name="Innes">{{cite journal | author=Mitchell-Innes, Alfred |title=The Credit Theory of Money |journal= The Banking Law Journal | year=1914 |volume=31 |url=https://www.community-exchange.org/docs/The%20Credit%20Theoriy%20of%20Money.htm}}</ref> Innes argued:
{{Quotation|Whenever a tax is imposed, each taxpayer becomes responsible for the redemption of a small part of the debt which the government has contracted by its issues of money, whether coins, certificates, notes, drafts on the treasury, or by whatever name this money is called. He has to acquire his portion of the debt from some holder of a coin or certificate or other form of government money, and present it to the Treasury in liquidation of his legal debt. He has to redeem or cancel that portion of the debt...The redemption of government debt by taxation is the basic law of coinage and of any issue of government ‘money’ in whatever form.|Alfred Mitchell-Innes|The Credit Theory of Money|The Banking Law Journal|}}

Knapp and "Chartalism" were referenced by [[John Maynard Keynes]] in the opening pages of his 1930 ''[[A Treatise on Money|Treatise on Money]]'' <ref>Keynes, John Maynard: ''A Treatise on Money'', 1930, pp. 4, 6</ref> and appear to have influenced [[Keynesian]] ideas on the role of the state in the economy.<ref name="wray2000">{{Harv|Wray|2000}}</ref>
By 1947, when [[Abba Lerner]] wrote his article "Money as a Creature of the State", economists had largely abandoned the idea that the value of money was closely linked to gold.<ref name=Lerner /> Lerner argued that responsibility for avoiding inflation and depressions lay with the state because of its ability to create or tax away money.<ref name=Lerner>{{cite journal| last="Lerner" | first=Abba P. | journal=The American Economic Review | title=Money as a Creature of the State | volume=37 | number=2, |date=May 1947}}</ref>


==Modern proponents==
==Modern proponents==
{{also|Modern Monetary Theory}}
{{also|Modern Monetary Theory}}
Economists [[Warren Mosler]], [[L. Randall Wray]], [[Stephanie Kelton]], and [[Bill Mitchell (economist)|Bill Mitchell]] are largely responsible for reviving chartalism as an explanation of [[money creation]]; Wray refers to this revived formulation as ''Neo-Chartalism''.<ref>[http://www.economist.com/node/21542174 The Economist, 31 December 2011, "Marginal revolutionaries"] neo-chartalism, sometimes called “Modern Monetary Theory”</ref>
Economists [[Warren Mosler]], [[L. Randall Wray]], [[Stephanie Kelton]], and [[Bill Mitchell (economist)|Bill Mitchell]] are largely responsible for reviving chartalism as an explanation of [[money creation]]; Wray refers to this revived formulation as ''Neo-Chartalism''.<ref>[https://www.economist.com/node/21542174 The Economist, 31 December 2011, "Marginal revolutionaries"] neo-chartalism, sometimes called “Modern Monetary Theory”</ref>


Mitchell, founder of the Centre of Full Employment and Equity or [[Centre of Full Employment and Equity|CofFEE]] at the [[University of Newcastle, Australia|University of Newcastle]] in Australia, coined the term [[Modern Monetary Theory]] to describe modern Neo-Chartalism, and that term is now widely used. Scott Fullwiler has added detailed technical analysis of the banking and monetary systems.<ref>http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/cf_dev/AbsByAuth.cfm?per_id=444041</ref>
Mitchell, founder of the Centre of Full Employment and Equity or [[Centre of Full Employment and Equity|CofFEE]] at the [[University of Newcastle, Australia|University of Newcastle]] in Australia, coined the term [[Modern Monetary Theory]] to describe modern Neo-Chartalism, and that term is now widely used. Scott Fullwiler has added detailed technical analysis of the banking and monetary systems.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/cf_dev/AbsByAuth.cfm?per_id=444041|title=Author Page for Scott Fullwiler :: SSRN}}</ref>


Rodger Malcolm Mitchell's 1996 book ''Free Money''<ref>Mitchell, Rodger Malcolm: ''Free Money - Plan for Prosperity'', PGM International, Inc., paperback 2005, {{ISBN|978-0-9658323-1-1}}</ref> describes in layman's terms the essence of chartalism.
Rodger Malcolm Mitchell's book ''Free Money''<ref>Mitchell, Rodger Malcolm: ''Free Money - Plan for Prosperity'', PGM International, Inc., paperback 2005, {{ISBN|978-0-9658323-1-1}}</ref> describes in layman's terms the essence of chartalism.


Some contemporary proponents, such as Wray, situate chartalism within [[post-Keynesian economics]], while chartalism has been proposed as an alternative or complementary theory to [[monetary circuit theory]], both being forms of [[endogenous money]], i.e., money created within the economy, as by government deficit spending or bank lending, rather than from outside, as by gold. In the complementary view, chartalism explains the "vertical" (government-to-private and vice versa) interactions, while circuit theory is a model of the "horizontal" (private-to-private) interactions.<ref name=def1013>[http://bilbo.economicoutlook.net/blog/?p=381 "Deficit Spending 101 - Part 3"] Bill Mitchell, 2 March 2009</ref><ref>[http://bilbo.economicoutlook.net/blog/?p=5199 "In the spirit of debate...my reply"] Bill Mitchell, 28 September 2009</ref>
Some contemporary proponents, such as Wray, situate chartalism within [[post-Keynesian economics]], while chartalism has been proposed as an alternative or complementary theory to [[monetary circuit theory]], both being forms of [[endogenous money]], i.e., money created within the economy, as by government deficit spending or bank lending, rather than from outside, as by gold. In the complementary view, chartalism explains the "vertical" (government-to-private and vice versa) interactions, while circuit theory is a model of the "horizontal" (private-to-private) interactions.<ref name=def1013>[http://bilbo.economicoutlook.net/blog/?p=381 "Deficit Spending 101 - Part 3"] Bill Mitchell, 2 March 2009</ref><ref>[http://bilbo.economicoutlook.net/blog/?p=5199 "In the spirit of debate...my reply"] Bill Mitchell, 28 September 2009</ref>
Line 45: Line 49:


[[James K. Galbraith]] supports chartalism and wrote the foreword for Mosler's book ''Seven Deadly Innocent Frauds of Economic Policy'' in 2010.<ref>Mosler, Warren: ''Seven Deadly Innocent Frauds of Economic Policy'', Valance Co., 2010, {{ISBN|978-0-692-00959-8}}; also available in [http://www.moslereconomics.com/wp-content/powerpoints/7DIF2.doc .DOC]</ref>
[[James K. Galbraith]] supports chartalism and wrote the foreword for Mosler's book ''Seven Deadly Innocent Frauds of Economic Policy'' in 2010.<ref>Mosler, Warren: ''Seven Deadly Innocent Frauds of Economic Policy'', Valance Co., 2010, {{ISBN|978-0-692-00959-8}}; also available in [http://www.moslereconomics.com/wp-content/powerpoints/7DIF2.doc .DOC]</ref>

== Criticism ==
The continued use of the [[Somali shilling]] as currency despite the lack of a functioning central government capable of raising taxes or a central bank to issue it has been cited as a counterargument to Chartalism.<ref>https://jpkoning.blogspot.com/2013/03/orphaned-currency-odd-case-of-somali.html</ref> [[Bitcoin]], a [[cryptocurrency]] not originated by a state, has also been cited as a counterexample.<ref>https://www.forbes.com/sites/jonmatonis/2013/04/03/bitcoin-obliterates-the-state-theory-of-money/</ref>


== See also ==
== See also ==
Line 59: Line 60:
{{Reflist}}
{{Reflist}}


{{Schools of economic thought}}
{{Macroeconomics}}
{{Macroeconomics}}
{{Economics}}
{{Means of Exchange}}


[[Category:Monetary economics]]
[[Category:Monetary economics]]

Latest revision as of 08:06, 30 October 2023

In macroeconomics, chartalism is a heterodox theory of money that argues that money originated historically with states' attempts to direct economic activity rather than as a spontaneous solution to the problems with barter or as a means with which to tokenize debt,[1] and that fiat currency has value in exchange because of sovereign power to levy taxes on economic activity payable in the currency they issue.

Background

[edit]

Georg Friedrich Knapp, a German economist, invented the term "chartalism" in his State Theory of Money, which was published in German in 1905 and translated into English in 1924. The name derives from the Latin charta, in the sense of a token or ticket.[2] Knapp argued that "money is a creature of law" rather than a commodity.[3] Knapp contrasted his state theory of money with "metallism", as embodied at the time in the gold standard, where the value of a unit of currency depended on the quantity of precious metal it contained or could be exchanged for. He argued the state could create pure paper money and make it exchangeable by recognising it as legal tender, with the criterion for the money of a state being "that which is accepted at the public pay offices".[3]

When Knapp was writing, the prevailing view of money was that it had evolved from systems of barter to become a medium of exchange because it represented a durable commodity which had some use value. However, as modern chartalist economists such as Randall Wray and Mathew Forstater have pointed out, chartalist insights into tax-driven paper money can be found in the earlier writings of many classical economists,[4][5] for instance Adam Smith, who observed in The Wealth of Nations:

A prince, who should enact that a certain proportion of his taxes should be paid in a paper money of a certain kind, might thereby give a certain value to this paper money; even though the term of its final discharge and redemption should depend altogether on the will of the prince.

— Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations

Forstater also finds support for the concept of tax-driven money, under certain institutional conditions, in the work of Jean-Baptiste Say, John Stuart Mill, Karl Marx and William Stanley Jevons.[5]

Alfred Mitchell-Innes, writing in 1914, argued that money existed not as a medium of exchange but as a standard of deferred payment, with government money being debt the government could reclaim by taxation.[6] Innes argued:

Whenever a tax is imposed, each taxpayer becomes responsible for the redemption of a small part of the debt which the government has contracted by its issues of money, whether coins, certificates, notes, drafts on the treasury, or by whatever name this money is called. He has to acquire his portion of the debt from some holder of a coin or certificate or other form of government money, and present it to the Treasury in liquidation of his legal debt. He has to redeem or cancel that portion of the debt...The redemption of government debt by taxation is the basic law of coinage and of any issue of government ‘money’ in whatever form.

— Alfred Mitchell-Innes, The Credit Theory of Money, The Banking Law Journal

Knapp and "Chartalism" were referenced by John Maynard Keynes in the opening pages of his 1930 Treatise on Money [7] and appear to have influenced Keynesian ideas on the role of the state in the economy.[4] By 1947, when Abba Lerner wrote his article "Money as a Creature of the State", economists had largely abandoned the idea that the value of money was closely linked to gold.[8] Lerner argued that responsibility for avoiding inflation and depressions lay with the state because of its ability to create or tax away money.[8]

Historian Constantina Katsari sees principles from both metallism and chartalism reflected in the monetary system introduced by Augustus to the eastern provinces of the Roman Empire, from the early 1st century to the late 3rd century AD.[9][10]

Modern proponents

[edit]

Economists Warren Mosler, L. Randall Wray, Stephanie Kelton, and Bill Mitchell are largely responsible for reviving chartalism as an explanation of money creation; Wray refers to this revived formulation as Neo-Chartalism.[11]

Mitchell, founder of the Centre of Full Employment and Equity or CofFEE at the University of Newcastle in Australia, coined the term Modern Monetary Theory to describe modern Neo-Chartalism, and that term is now widely used. Scott Fullwiler has added detailed technical analysis of the banking and monetary systems.[12]

Rodger Malcolm Mitchell's book Free Money[13] describes in layman's terms the essence of chartalism.

Some contemporary proponents, such as Wray, situate chartalism within post-Keynesian economics, while chartalism has been proposed as an alternative or complementary theory to monetary circuit theory, both being forms of endogenous money, i.e., money created within the economy, as by government deficit spending or bank lending, rather than from outside, as by gold. In the complementary view, chartalism explains the "vertical" (government-to-private and vice versa) interactions, while circuit theory is a model of the "horizontal" (private-to-private) interactions.[14][15]

Hyman Minsky seemed to incorporate a Chartalist approach to money creation in his Stabilizing an Unstable Economy,[16] while Basil Moore, in his book Horizontalists and Verticalists,[17] delineates the differences between bank money and state money.

James K. Galbraith supports chartalism and wrote the foreword for Mosler's book Seven Deadly Innocent Frauds of Economic Policy in 2010.[18]

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ Graeber, David (12 July 2011). Debt: The First 5000 Years. ISBN 978-1-933633-86-2.
  2. ^ Knapp, George Friedrich (1924), The State Theory of Money, Macmillan and Company, p. 32
  3. ^ a b Knapp, George Friedrich (1924), The State Theory of Money, Macmillan and Company
  4. ^ a b Wray, L. Randall (2000), The Neo-Chartalist Approach to Money, UMKC Center for Full Employment and Price Stability, archived from the original on 2019-10-20, retrieved 2019-08-27
  5. ^ a b Forstater, Mathew (2004), Tax-Driven Money: Additional Evidence from the History of Thought, Economic History, and Economic Policy (PDF), archived from the original (PDF) on 2020-04-20, retrieved 2014-07-28
  6. ^ Mitchell-Innes, Alfred (1914). "The Credit Theory of Money". The Banking Law Journal. 31.
  7. ^ Keynes, John Maynard: A Treatise on Money, 1930, pp. 4, 6
  8. ^ a b Lerner, Abba P. (May 1947). "Money as a Creature of the State". The American Economic Review. 37 (2).
  9. ^ Stephanie A. Bell and Edward J. Nell, ed. (2003). The State, the Market, and the Euro: Chartalism Versus Metallism in the theory of money. Edward Elgar. ISBN 1843761564.
  10. ^ Constantina Katsari (2011). "Chpt. 7". The Roman Monetary System. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521769464.
  11. ^ The Economist, 31 December 2011, "Marginal revolutionaries" neo-chartalism, sometimes called “Modern Monetary Theory”
  12. ^ "Author Page for Scott Fullwiler :: SSRN".
  13. ^ Mitchell, Rodger Malcolm: Free Money - Plan for Prosperity, PGM International, Inc., paperback 2005, ISBN 978-0-9658323-1-1
  14. ^ "Deficit Spending 101 - Part 3" Bill Mitchell, 2 March 2009
  15. ^ "In the spirit of debate...my reply" Bill Mitchell, 28 September 2009
  16. ^ Minsky, Hyman: Stabilizing an Unstable Economy, McGraw-Hill, 2008, ISBN 978-0-07-159299-4
  17. ^ Moore, Basil J.: Horizontalists and Verticalists: The Macroeconomics of Credit Money, Cambridge University Press, 1988, ISBN 978-0-521-35079-2
  18. ^ Mosler, Warren: Seven Deadly Innocent Frauds of Economic Policy, Valance Co., 2010, ISBN 978-0-692-00959-8; also available in .DOC