Transportation theory (mathematics)

(Redirected from Optimal transport)

In mathematics and economics, transportation theory or transport theory is a name given to the study of optimal transportation and allocation of resources. The problem was formalized by the French mathematician Gaspard Monge in 1781.[1]

In the 1920s A.N. Tolstoi was one of the first to study the transportation problem mathematically. In 1930, in the collection Transportation Planning Volume I for the National Commissariat of Transportation of the Soviet Union, he published a paper "Methods of Finding the Minimal Kilometrage in Cargo-transportation in space".[2][3]

Major advances were made in the field during World War II by the Soviet mathematician and economist Leonid Kantorovich.[4] Consequently, the problem as it is stated is sometimes known as the Monge–Kantorovich transportation problem.[5] The linear programming formulation of the transportation problem is also known as the HitchcockKoopmans transportation problem.[6]

Motivation

edit

Mines and factories

edit

Suppose that we have a collection of   mines mining iron ore, and a collection of   factories which use the iron ore that the mines produce. Suppose for the sake of argument that these mines and factories form two disjoint subsets   and   of the Euclidean plane  . Suppose also that we have a cost function  , so that   is the cost of transporting one shipment of iron from   to  . For simplicity, we ignore the time taken to do the transporting. We also assume that each mine can supply only one factory (no splitting of shipments) and that each factory requires precisely one shipment to be in operation (factories cannot work at half- or double-capacity). Having made the above assumptions, a transport plan is a bijection  . In other words, each mine   supplies precisely one target factory   and each factory is supplied by precisely one mine. We wish to find the optimal transport plan, the plan   whose total cost

 

is the least of all possible transport plans from   to  . This motivating special case of the transportation problem is an instance of the assignment problem. More specifically, it is equivalent to finding a minimum weight matching in a bipartite graph.

Moving books: the importance of the cost function

edit

The following simple example illustrates the importance of the cost function in determining the optimal transport plan. Suppose that we have   books of equal width on a shelf (the real line), arranged in a single contiguous block. We wish to rearrange them into another contiguous block, but shifted one book-width to the right. Two obvious candidates for the optimal transport plan present themselves:

  1. move all   books one book-width to the right ("many small moves");
  2. move the left-most book   book-widths to the right and leave all other books fixed ("one big move").

If the cost function is proportional to Euclidean distance (  for some  ) then these two candidates are both optimal. If, on the other hand, we choose the strictly convex cost function proportional to the square of Euclidean distance (  for some  ), then the "many small moves" option becomes the unique minimizer.

Note that the above cost functions consider only the horizontal distance traveled by the books, not the horizontal distance traveled by a device used to pick each book up and move the book into position. If the latter is considered instead, then, of the two transport plans, the second is always optimal for the Euclidean distance, while, provided there are at least 3 books, the first transport plan is optimal for the squared Euclidean distance.

Hitchcock problem

edit

The following transportation problem formulation is credited to F. L. Hitchcock:[7]

Suppose there are   sources   for a commodity, with   units of supply at   and   sinks   for the commodity, with the demand   at  . If   is the unit cost of shipment from   to  , find a flow that satisfies demand from supplies and minimizes the flow cost. This challenge in logistics was taken up by D. R. Fulkerson[8] and in the book Flows in Networks (1962) written with L. R. Ford Jr.[9]

Tjalling Koopmans is also credited with formulations of transport economics and allocation of resources.

Abstract formulation of the problem

edit

Monge and Kantorovich formulations

edit

The transportation problem as it is stated in modern or more technical literature looks somewhat different because of the development of Riemannian geometry and measure theory. The mines-factories example, simple as it is, is a useful reference point when thinking of the abstract case. In this setting, we allow the possibility that we may not wish to keep all mines and factories open for business, and allow mines to supply more than one factory, and factories to accept iron from more than one mine.

Let   and   be two separable metric spaces such that any probability measure on   (or  ) is a Radon measure (i.e. they are Radon spaces). Let   be a Borel-measurable function. Given probability measures   on   and   on  , Monge's formulation of the optimal transportation problem is to find a transport map   that realizes the infimum

 

where   denotes the push forward of   by  . A map   that attains this infimum (i.e. makes it a minimum instead of an infimum) is called an "optimal transport map".

Monge's formulation of the optimal transportation problem can be ill-posed, because sometimes there is no   satisfying  : this happens, for example, when   is a Dirac measure but   is not.

We can improve on this by adopting Kantorovich's formulation of the optimal transportation problem, which is to find a probability measure   on   that attains the infimum

 

where   denotes the collection of all probability measures on   with marginals   on   and   on  . It can be shown[10] that a minimizer for this problem always exists when the cost function   is lower semi-continuous and   is a tight collection of measures (which is guaranteed for Radon spaces   and  ). (Compare this formulation with the definition of the Wasserstein metric   on the space of probability measures.) A gradient descent formulation for the solution of the Monge–Kantorovich problem was given by Sigurd Angenent, Steven Haker, and Allen Tannenbaum.[11]

Duality formula

edit

The minimum of the Kantorovich problem is equal to

 

where the supremum runs over all pairs of bounded and continuous functions   and   such that

 

Economic interpretation

edit

The economic interpretation is clearer if signs are flipped. Let   stand for the vector of characteristics of a worker,   for the vector of characteristics of a firm, and   for the economic output generated by worker   matched with firm  . Setting   and  , the Monge–Kantorovich problem rewrites:   which has dual :   where the infimum runs over bounded and continuous function   and  . If the dual problem has a solution, one can see that:   so that   interprets as the equilibrium wage of a worker of type  , and   interprets as the equilibrium profit of a firm of type  .[12]

Solution of the problem

edit

Optimal transportation on the real line

edit
 
Optimal transportation matrix
 
Continuous optimal transport

For  , let   denote the collection of probability measures on   that have finite  -th moment. Let   and let  , where   is a convex function.

  1. If   has no atom, i.e., if the cumulative distribution function   of   is a continuous function, then   is an optimal transport map. It is the unique optimal transport map if   is strictly convex.
  2. We have
 

The proof of this solution appears in Rachev & Rüschendorf (1998).[13]

Discrete version and linear programming formulation

edit

In the case where the margins   and   are discrete, let   and   be the probability masses respectively assigned to   and  , and let   be the probability of an   assignment. The objective function in the primal Kantorovich problem is then

 

and the constraint   expresses as

 

and

 

In order to input this in a linear programming problem, we need to vectorize the matrix   by either stacking its columns or its rows, we call   this operation. In the column-major order, the constraints above rewrite as

  and  

where   is the Kronecker product,   is a matrix of size   with all entries of ones, and   is the identity matrix of size  . As a result, setting  , the linear programming formulation of the problem is

 

which can be readily inputted in a large-scale linear programming solver (see chapter 3.4 of Galichon (2016)[12]).

Semi-discrete case

edit

In the semi-discrete case,   and   is a continuous distribution over  , while   is a discrete distribution which assigns probability mass   to site  . In this case, we can see[14] that the primal and dual Kantorovich problems respectively boil down to:   for the primal, where   means that   and  , and:   for the dual, which can be rewritten as:   which is a finite-dimensional convex optimization problem that can be solved by standard techniques, such as gradient descent.

In the case when  , one can show that the set of   assigned to a particular site   is a convex polyhedron. The resulting configuration is called a power diagram.[15]

Quadratic normal case

edit

Assume the particular case  ,  , and   where   is invertible. One then has

 
 
 

The proof of this solution appears in Galichon (2016).[12]

Separable Hilbert spaces

edit

Let   be a separable Hilbert space. Let   denote the collection of probability measures on   that have finite  -th moment; let   denote those elements   that are Gaussian regular: if   is any strictly positive Gaussian measure on   and  , then   also.

Let  ,  ,   for  . Then the Kantorovich problem has a unique solution  , and this solution is induced by an optimal transport map: i.e., there exists a Borel map   such that

 

Moreover, if   has bounded support, then

 

for  -almost all   for some locally Lipschitz,  -concave and maximal Kantorovich potential  . (Here   denotes the Gateaux derivative of  .)

Entropic regularization

edit

Consider a variant of the discrete problem above, where we have added an entropic regularization term to the objective function of the primal problem

 

One can show that the dual regularized problem is

 

where, compared with the unregularized version, the "hard" constraint in the former dual ( ) has been replaced by a "soft" penalization of that constraint (the sum of the   terms ). The optimality conditions in the dual problem can be expressed as

Eq. 5.1:  
Eq. 5.2:  

Denoting   as the   matrix of term  , solving the dual is therefore equivalent to looking for two diagonal positive matrices   and   of respective sizes   and  , such that   and  . The existence of such matrices generalizes Sinkhorn's theorem and the matrices can be computed using the Sinkhorn–Knopp algorithm,[16] which simply consists of iteratively looking for   to solve Equation 5.1, and   to solve Equation 5.2. Sinkhorn–Knopp's algorithm is therefore a coordinate descent algorithm on the dual regularized problem.

Applications

edit

The Monge–Kantorovich optimal transport has found applications in wide range in different fields. Among them are:

See also

edit

References

edit
  1. ^ G. Monge. Mémoire sur la théorie des déblais et des remblais. Histoire de l’Académie Royale des Sciences de Paris, avec les Mémoires de Mathématique et de Physique pour la même année, pages 666–704, 1781.
  2. ^ Schrijver, Alexander, Combinatorial Optimization, Berlin; New York : Springer, 2003. ISBN 3540443894. Cf. p. 362
  3. ^ Ivor Grattan-Guinness, Ivor, Companion encyclopedia of the history and philosophy of the mathematical sciences, Volume 1, JHU Press, 2003. Cf. p.831
  4. ^ L. Kantorovich. On the translocation of masses. C.R. (Doklady) Acad. Sci. URSS (N.S.), 37:199–201, 1942.
  5. ^ Cédric Villani (2003). Topics in Optimal Transportation. American Mathematical Soc. p. 66. ISBN 978-0-8218-3312-4.
  6. ^ Singiresu S. Rao (2009). Engineering Optimization: Theory and Practice (4th ed.). John Wiley & Sons. p. 221. ISBN 978-0-470-18352-6.
  7. ^ Frank L. Hitchcock (1941) "The distribution of a product from several sources to numerous localities", MIT Journal of Mathematics and Physics 20:224–230 MR0004469.
  8. ^ D. R. Fulkerson (1956) Hitchcock Transportation Problem, RAND corporation.
  9. ^ L. R. Ford Jr. & D. R. Fulkerson (1962) § 3.1 in Flows in Networks, page 95, Princeton University Press
  10. ^ L. Ambrosio, N. Gigli & G. Savaré. Gradient Flows in Metric Spaces and in the Space of Probability Measures. Lectures in Mathematics ETH Zürich, Birkhäuser Verlag, Basel. (2005)
  11. ^ Angenent, S.; Haker, S.; Tannenbaum, A. (2003). "Minimizing flows for the Monge–Kantorovich problem". SIAM J. Math. Anal. 35 (1): 61–97. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.424.1064. doi:10.1137/S0036141002410927.
  12. ^ a b c Galichon, Alfred. Optimal Transport Methods in Economics. Princeton University Press, 2016.
  13. ^ Rachev, Svetlozar T., and Ludger Rüschendorf. Mass Transportation Problems: Volume I: Theory. Vol. 1. Springer, 1998.
  14. ^ Santambrogio, Filippo. Optimal Transport for Applied Mathematicians. Birkhäuser Basel, 2016. In particular chapter 6, section 4.2.
  15. ^ Aurenhammer, Franz (1987), "Power diagrams: properties, algorithms and applications", SIAM Journal on Computing, 16 (1): 78–96, doi:10.1137/0216006, MR 0873251.
  16. ^ Peyré, Gabriel and Marco Cuturi (2019), "Computational Optimal Transport: With Applications to Data Science", Foundations and Trends in Machine Learning: Vol. 11: No. 5-6, pp 355–607. DOI: 10.1561/2200000073.
  17. ^ Haker, Steven; Zhu, Lei; Tannenbaum, Allen; Angenent, Sigurd (1 December 2004). "Optimal Mass Transport for Registration and Warping". International Journal of Computer Vision. 60 (3): 225–240. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.59.4082. doi:10.1023/B:VISI.0000036836.66311.97. ISSN 0920-5691. S2CID 13261370.
  18. ^ Glimm, T.; Oliker, V. (1 September 2003). "Optical Design of Single Reflector Systems and the Monge–Kantorovich Mass Transfer Problem". Journal of Mathematical Sciences. 117 (3): 4096–4108. doi:10.1023/A:1024856201493. ISSN 1072-3374. S2CID 8301248.
  19. ^ Kasim, Muhammad Firmansyah; Ceurvorst, Luke; Ratan, Naren; Sadler, James; Chen, Nicholas; Sävert, Alexander; Trines, Raoul; Bingham, Robert; Burrows, Philip N. (16 February 2017). "Quantitative shadowgraphy and proton radiography for large intensity modulations". Physical Review E. 95 (2): 023306. arXiv:1607.04179. Bibcode:2017PhRvE..95b3306K. doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.95.023306. PMID 28297858. S2CID 13326345.
  20. ^ Metivier, Ludovic (24 February 2016). "Measuring the misfit between seismograms using an optimal transport distance: application to full waveform inversion". Geophysical Journal International. 205 (1): 345–377. Bibcode:2016GeoJI.205..345M. doi:10.1093/gji/ggw014.

Further reading

edit